Tropical Forest Conservation PDF
Tropical Forest Conservation PDF
DOUGLAS SOUTHGATE
1998
Oxford University Press
Oxford New York
Athens Auckland Bangkok Bogota Bombay
Buenos Aires Calcutta Cape Town Dar es Salaam
Delhi Florence Hong Kong Istanbul Karachi
Kuala Lumpur Madras Madrid Melbourne
Mexico City Nairobi Paris Singapore
Taipei Tokyo Toronto Warsaw
and associated companies in
Berlin Ibadan
9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
Printed in the United States of America
on acid free, recycled paper
Acknowledgments
Abbreviations 151
References 153
Index 167
Introduction
Responding to the Challenge of Habitat
Destruction in Latin America
ix
x Introduction
3
4 Deforestation and Its Causes
11
12 Deforestation and Its Causes
for Africa and Asia are 0.16 and 0.13 hectares per person,
respectively. The reasons for the discrepancy between South
America and the rest of the developing world are not clear.
One might think that higher land-clearing coefficients for
Brazil and neighboring countries are the result of forests be-
ing converted mainly into low-density cattle pastures. But
the truth is that Asia is the place where pasture represents
the more prevalent new land use, with 92 percent of the de-
forested area being dedicated to livestock production, as op-
posed to 47 percent in South America and 29 percent in
Africa (Pearce, 1996).
Obviously, other things are going on, at least in the West-
ern Hemisphere.
25
26 Deforestation and Its Causes
pioneer nutrient miners are poorly educated and they are apt
to find that dealing with an agency, bank, or any other insti-
tution is a frustrating experience.
Where formal property rights have not been established,
the advantages of people who are more affluent and well con-
nected count for little. Also, the opportunity costs of the time
they devote to defending a claim in a remote region, where
the government's presence is negligible, are not covered by
that activity's returns. However, those same returns are suf-
ficiently attractive to colonists, whose time carries a low op-
portunity cost.
The tables turn once government begins to guarantee land
tenure. Landowners are no longer obliged to occupy their
holdings at all times so as to keep trespassers in check. In
addition, the articulation of property arrangements makes it
possible for formal financial institutions to function. When
this happens, people with good access to those institutions—
which lend money at interest rates substantially below what
informal lenders charge—can borrow money to buy real es-
tate, quite often from the original occupants. Wealthier peo-
ple with better connections have other advantages. Their
management skills tend to be superior. Furthermore, they
find it relatively easy to arrange for government to provide
them with land protection services.
Moran (1989) has documented that institutional and eco-
nomic development in a frontier region is accompanied by a
transition from one type of owner to another. Also, the survey
of INCRA land settlement projects reveals that turnover of
holdings has been high in the Amazon Basin (FAO/UNDP/
MARA, 1992, cited in Schneider, 1995, p. 12), which is con-
sistent with the transition in land ownership.
After selling out or otherwise giving ground in areas un-
dergoing development, pioneer nutrient miners' choices are
very limited. Indeed, those choices are not appreciably dif-
ferent from those facing the rural poor throughout Latin
America. If they do not migrate, their rudimentary skills per-
mit them to hold only menial, low-paying jobs. Seasonal farm
labor and casual employment in the wood products sector
would be two examples. Another choice, which does not ex-
clude the first, is to support oneself and one's family as best
as one can on a small holding, located perhaps in an area
where property rights remain weak or nonexistent.
Another option is to abandon the countryside, and then to
crowd into the urban slums where hundreds of thousands of
people already live in Belem, Manaus, and a number of me-
30 Deforestation and Its Causes
43
44 Economic Returns
59
60 Economic Returns
Riparian Logging
One IMAZON study, carried out by Barros and Uhl (1995),
addresses the oldest form of forest exploitation in the Brazil-
ian Amazon. In the seventeenth century, the two investiga-
tors point out, high-quality timber began to be harvested
Environmentally Sound Timber Production 61
ber at exactly the same time (as noted above) and 50 percent
higher than the price for logs extracted from dry lands close
to navigable rivers a year or two later (see Table 5.1). Re-
sponding to higher prices, wood processing firms had chosen
to operate at somewhat improved levels of efficiency. Instead
of three cubic meters of raw materials being used to produce
one cubic meter of output, as was the case in Tailandia. 47
percent of the roundwood going into a typical mill was
emerging as finished product (Verrissimo et al., 1992).
Stumpage prices, however, were not much higher in the
old frontier region than they were where resources were more
abundant. As of 1989, a cubic meter of uncut timber in the
Paragominas region was worth $1.84 (Verrissimo et al.,
1992), compared to $.80 around Tailandia. One reason why
prices remained low was that trucking in logs from other lo-
cations is not prohibitively expensive. In addition, process-
ing facilities (e.g., small band-saw mills) can be moved from
place to place without great difficulty. So can labor. In gen-
eral, a high level of factor mobility diminished location-
al rents in the late 1980s, and has continued to do so to
this day.
Since prices of standing timber have not risen very much
in the vicinity of Paragominas, resource owners and loggers
have been slow to adopt better management practices. Ver-
rissimo et al. (1992) carried out an economic analysis of two
such practices. The first is vine removal at least eighteen
months before a harvest, which reduces collateral damage to
commercial species left in the forest. The second is the prac-
tice of refinement thinnings, which promotes the growth of
those same species after logging has taken place. Together,
these two practices were estimated to cost $120 per hectare.
But even this modest expenditure was found not to be re-
munerative under market conditions that prevailed in the
late 1980s.
Since that time, deforestation has continued in the Para-
gominas region, which in turn has caused timber to become
even more scarce. Stumpage prices currently exceed $5 per
cubic meter (Paulo Barreto, personal communication, 1996),
and mills are now paying more than $35 per cubic meter for
roundwood. A recent IMAZON-sponsored survey of the re-
gion's wood-products industry indicates that several smaller
mills, which can relocate fairly easily, have departed, pre-
sumably for areas where agricultural land clearing has not
reached such an advanced stage. But less mobile plants, like
veneer factories, are responding to higher prices by making
70 Economic Returns
From the outset, PEPP met with fierce opposition from the
indigenous Yanesha (also known as Amuesha) communities
and their Peruvian and foreign allies. Responding to these
criticisms, and the cautionary advice of its own consultants
(Smith, 1982, cited in Benavides and Pariona, 1995), AID
decided not to back colonization. Instead, $22 million, in-
cluding $4 million for technical assistance and project de-
velopment, was allotted to the Central Selva Resource Man-
agement Project (CSRMP). A protected reserve was to be set
up and managed and a system for sustainable timber exploi-
tation was to be developed and applied. Environmentally
sound agricultural production was to be promoted and pub-
lic health services were to be upgraded as well.
As stressed by an expert affiliated with Costa Rica's Trop-
ical Science Center (TSC), which provided technical assis-
tance to the CSRMP's forestry component, the challenges of
sustaining timber resource development in a place like the
Palcazu Valley were considerable (Hartshorn, 1990). Govern-
ment policies have accelerated agricultural land clearing and
public sector institutions have had little or no capacity for
furnishing useful advice to those with a potential interest in
forest management. Low concentrations of commercial tim-
ber and high extraction costs were additional problems. In
addition, there was a negligible level of understanding of
tropical forest dynamics and the regeneration requirements
of canopy tree species.
The CSRMP did not address policy issues or attempt a
thorough overhaul of institutions engaged in forestry re-
search and extension. Instead, primary emphasis was placed
on developing and promoting an alternative to the usual pat-
tern of unplanned high-grading of a limited number of spe-
cies, which is what takes place throughout the Brazilian
Amazon (as noted previously) and elsewhere in the Ameri-
can tropics. TSC investigators were convinced that an alter-
native approach was viable since, along with national and
international demand for fine tropical woods, local and na-
tional markets exist for a wide variety of species. The impli-
Environmentally Sound Timber Production 73
Project Performance
Reflecting subsequently on the forestry activities he carried
out with COFYAL, Simeone (1990) observed that outside
technical assistance would be needed for many years if the
production, harvesting, and milling scheme and marketing
initiatives were to succeed. Poor performance of the system
Environmentally Sound Timber Production 75
Lessons Learned
83
84 Economic Returns
They also reported that, as of the early 1980s, only 5,000 spe-
cies had been examined thoroughly and that, of that number,
40 were found to contain commercially useful medicinal in-
gredients. Applying an implicit rate of 1 research success per
125 species to one-fortieth of the gross value of plant-derived
prescriptions, Farnsworth and Soejarto (1985) contended
that the worth in the United States of an untested species is
$1.63 million, in 1980 dollars:
1/125 X 1/40 X $8.128 billion =
$1.63 million per untested species.
95
96 Economic Returns
the sort that most foreign tourists (or at least those who are
prepared to spend more than token sums of money) would
care to patronize, those facilities are often self-contained,
providing direct benefits to nearby communities only in the
form of the low wages paid to waiters, maids, and other un-
skilled laborers.
For some protected areas, local economic impacts are
practically nonexistent. For example, nearly everyone who
visits Volcan Poas or Volcan Irazu does so on a half-day ex-
cursion from San Jose, which any hotel or guesthouse can
easily arrange. Most visitors purchase little or nothing from
people living around the park. Even at La Selva, the local
returns are not all that great; Rovinski (1991) reports that the
13,000 individuals who visited the station in 1989 spent just
$291,000 in nearby settlements.
Pricing Issues
Conservation Initiatives
Ecuador first showed interest in protecting Galapagos wild-
life as the centennial of Darwin's visit approached. Two of
the country's earliest environmental laws relate directly to
the archipelago. A nature sanctuary was established there in
1934 and the hunting of selected island species was prohib-
ited two years later. However, these laws amounted to little
more than an expression of virtuous intent since effective
enforcement was precluded by the remoteness of the Gala-
pagos.
International involvement was catalyzed two decades later
by the United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural
Organization (UNESCO), which dispatched a field mission
in 1957, and by the International Union for the Conservation
of Nature (IUCN). The Charles Darwin Foundation was cre-
ated in 1959 to take charge of protecting endangered species,
and received official authorization to operate in the Galapa-
110 Economic Returns
charges are modest for those mainland parks that receive few
visitors. By contrast, the Costa Rican government has only
just begun to move away from a policy of charging all for-
eigners one uniform price for admission to any park and all
citizens of the country another price. Setting fees that better
reflect the differences among various sorts of visitors and
among various parks would allow the country to capture
more revenues, while at the same time redirecting people
away from places, like Manuel Antonio, where carrying ca-
pacities are probably being exceeded. Likewise, linking en-
trance fees to trip duration should be a central feature of
pricing policy, in the Galapagos and elsewhere.
Even if countries with appealing ecotourism destinations
price access efficiently, it will be rare for revenues generated
to exceed the expenses of protecting natural areas. Even at
Monteverde, the costs of intense maintenance and vigilant
protection, which are needed to secure the reserve, exceed
entrance fee revenues by a wide margin. Without donations
from foreign individuals and foundations, the site would de-
teriorate.
The Galapagos appear to be one of those unusual places
with the potential to be a net generator of funds, defined
broadly to consist of foreign donations as well as users' fees.
As noted in this chapter, it has long been a policy to use
monies collected from visitors and tourism businesses to
help pay for the management of mainland parks. If the recent
decisions by the Ministry of Finance are any guide, central
government officials are now casting an envious eye toward
those monies as well.
But even in the archipelago, it is important not to exag-
gerate the size of the financial surplus that ecotourism can
be expected to generate, year in and year out. Once habitat
protection has been adequately provided for, not much is
likely to be left over for local development initiatives or any-
thing else.
Ill
Key Elements of an Integrated
Strategy for Habitat Protection
and Economic Progress
This page intentionally left blank
8
Another Approach to
Habitat Conservation
Agricultural Intensification
123
124 An Integrated Strategy for Habitat Protection and Economic Progress
7.5% 10.0%
for the Green Revolution, which has boosted rice and wheat
yields, tropical deforestation in Asia would now be dis-
cussed mostly in the past tense. In the absence of intensifi-
cation, farmers and ranchers would have had to occupy every
available square meter in order to meet burgeoning food de-
mands, resulting from population growth and higher stan-
dards of living.
Results of a regression analysis of the causes of defores-
tation in the Brazilian Amazon (Reis and Guzman, 1994)
could be used to bolster the claim that intensification can
lead to land clearing. Indeed, those results reveal a link be-
tween increased crop output and deforestation at the county
[municipio] level. But in no way does this disprove the fact
that raising agricultural productivity tends to arrest farmers
and ranchers' overall encroachment on natural habitats. Con-
sistent with what Reis and Guzman (1994) have found, in-
tensification should cause cropland and pasture to expand at
the expense of forests in inframarginal areas—centrally lo-
cated municipios, in the case of the Brazilian Amazon. But
at the same time, agricultural land use should be diminishing
in more remote places. If more land is left undisturbed in
frontier areas than is cleared in inframarginal areas, then the
overall relationship between agricultural productivity in-
creases and deforestation is negative.
That there is, in fact, a negative linkage is indicated by the
findings of another regression study, one in which national-
level data are used (Southgate, 1994). In that study, annual
percentage growth in cropland and pasture during the mid-
dle 1980s (AGLNDGRO) is the dependent variable, and the
130 An Integrated Strategy for Habitat Protection and Economic Progress
135
136 An Integrated Strategy for Habitat Protection and Economic Progress
not land). When driving through the flat, fertile valleys east
of San Salvador, the national capital, one is struck by the
sight of primary irrigation canals leading up to the borders
of extensive cooperatives, which have not organized their
members to dig the secondary and tertiary canals needed to
distribute water to individual fields. Likewise, farm equip-
ment seems to have become extremely scarce on the coastal
plains, where rich volcanic soils once supported a thriving
cotton industry but where cooperatives now dominate and
the land is severely underutilized.
A lack of social capital also appears to explain some of the
inefficiencies and rigidities that characterize financial inter-
mediation in El Salvador. The level of participation in rural
credit markets is very low in the country, with only 31 per-
cent of farmers and rural households surveyed in early 1996
reporting having taken out a loan during the preceding five
years (Lopez, 1997). Government regulation is not the prob-
lem, now that interest-rate controls are a thing of the past.
Instead, limited lending in rural areas has a lot to do with
poor business prospects in the agricultural sector, which in
turn are related to an overvalued currency, inflexible real es-
tate markets, and other distortions. Furthermore, restricted
financial intermediation seems to reflect the fact that credit
sources, both formal and informal, are not confident that bor-
rowers can be obliged to repay. This is perhaps inevitable in
a country that has gone through the sort of conflict and social
dislocation that El Salvador recently experienced. (Of course,
the chance that a recalcitrant borrower owns a weapon, or
can easily get hold of one, has to cross a lender's mind from
time to time.)
Undertaking both the policy reforms and the social capital
improvements needed to make factor markets work better
would reduce rural poverty and ease pressure on the natural
resources on which poor people have come to depend. If land
and capital markets were more efficient, real estate would
end up in the hands of its highest and best users, including
productive small farmers, and more investment would take
place. Employment would increase, both on commercial
farms and in the agribusinesses that serve them. This would
benefit the rural poor directly, and would cause at least a few
of them to retire from the hillside plots where they now raise
corn, beans, and a few other crops.
Notwithstanding its importance, however, improving fac-
tor market efficiency is not the only condition needed for
rural development that is socially broad-based as well as en-
146 An Integrated Strategy for Habitat Protection and Economic Progress
151
152 Abbreviations
153
154 References
Pits Church against State," U.S. News and World Report 122:
24, pp. 30-32.
Romanoff, S. 1981. "Analisis de las Condiciones Socioeconomicas
para el Desarrollo Integral de la Amazonia Boliviana" (consult-
ing report), Organization of American States, Washington, B.C.
Romer, P. 1986. "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth" Journal
of Political Economy 94:5, pp. 1002-1037.
Rovinski, Y. 1991. "Private Reserves, Parks, and Ecotourism in
Costa Rica" in T. Whelan (ed.), Nature Tourism: Managing for
the Environment. Washington, B.C.: Island Press.
Ruitenbeek, H. 1989. "Social Cost-Benefit Analysis of the Korup
Project, Cameroon" (consulting report), Worldwide Fund for
Nature, London.
Salafsky, N., B. Bugelby, and J. Terborgh. 1992. "Can Extractive Re-
serves Save the Rainforest?," Buke University Center for Trop-
ical Conservation, Burham, N.C.
Salati, E. and P. Bose. 1984. "Amazon Basin: A System in Equilib-
rium," Science 225, pp. 129-138.
Scartezini, A. 1985. Segredos de Medici. Sao Paulo: Editora Marco
Zero.
Schneider, R. 1992. "Brazil: An Analysis of Environmental Prob-
lems in the Amazon" (report 9104-Br), World Bank, Washing-
ton, B.C.
Schneider, R. 1995. "Government and the Economy on the Amazon
Frontier" (environment paper 11), World Bank, Washington,
B.C.
Schwartzman, S. 1989. "Extractive Reserves: The Rubber Tap-
pers' Strategy for Sustainable Use of the Amazon Rain For-
est" in J. Browder (ed.), Fragile Lands of Latin America:
Strategies for Sustainable Development. Boulder, Colorado:
Westview Press.
Seitz, F. 1996. "A Major Beception on Global Warming," Wall Street
Journal, 12 June, p. A16.
Shaw, C. 1997. "Rural Land Markets" (report 16253-ES), World
Bank, Washington, B.C.
Simeone, R. 1990. "Land Use Planning and Forestry-Based Econ-
omy: The Case of the Amuesha Forestry Cooperative," Tebiwa:
The Journal of the Idaho Museum of Natural History 24, pp. 7-
12.
Simpson, B. and R. Sedjo. 1996. "Paying for the Conservation of
Endangered Ecosystems: A Comparison of Birect and Indirect
Approaches," Environment and Development Economics 1:2,
pp. 241-257.
Simpson, D., R. Sedjo, and J. Reid. 1996. "Valuing Biodiversity: An
Application to Genetic Prospecting," Journal of Political Econ-
omy 104:1, pp. 163-185.
Smith, N. 1981. "Colonization Lessons from a Tropical Forests,"
Science 214, pp. 755-761.
Smith, N., T. Fik, P. Alvim, I. Falesi, and E. Serrao. 1995. "Agrofo-
References 163
167
168 Index