Contemporary Imperialism, Samir Amin
Contemporary Imperialism, Samir Amin
Contemporary Imperialism, Samir Amin
SAMIR AMIN
L es s o n s f r o m t h e Tw e n t i e t h C e n t u r y
revolution. So what to do? How can the peasantry be linked with the
construction of socialism? By making concessions to the market and
by respecting newly acquired peasant property; hence by progressing
slowly towards socialism? The NEP implemented this strategy.
Yes, but…. Lenin, Bukharin, and Stalin also understood that the
imperialist powers would never accept the Revolution or even the
NEP. After the hot wars of intervention, the cold war was to become
permanent, from 1920 to 1990.2 Soviet Russia, even though it was far
from being able to construct socialism, was able to free itself from the
straightjacket that imperialism always strives to impose on all periph-
eries of the world system that it dominates. In effect, Soviet Russia
delinked. So what to do now? Attempt to push for peaceful coexistence,
by making concessions if necessary and refraining from intervening
too actively on the international stage? But at the same time, it was
necessary to be armed to face new and unavoidable attacks. And that
implied rapid industrialization, which, in turn, came into conflict with
the interests of the peasantry and thus threatened to break the worker-
peasant alliance, the foundation of the revolutionary state.
It is possible, then, to understand the equivocations of Lenin,
Bukharin, and Stalin. In theoretical terms, there were U-turns from
one extreme to the other. Sometimes a determinist attitude inspired
by the phased approach inherited from earlier Marxism (first the bour-
geois democratic revolution, then the socialist one) predominated,
sometimes a voluntarist approach (political action would make it pos-
sible to leap over stages). Finally, from 1930–1933, Stalin chose rapid
industrialization and armament (and this choice was not without some
connection to the rise of fascism). Collectivization was the price of that
choice. Here again we must beware of judging too quickly: all social-
ists of that period (and even more the capitalists) shared Kautsky’s
analyses on this point and were persuaded that the future belonged
to large-scale agriculture.3 The break in the worker-peasant alliance
that this choice implied lay behind the abandonment of revolutionary
democracy and the autocratic turn.
In my opinion, Trotsky would certainly not have done better. His
attitude towards the rebellion of the Kronstadt sailors and his later
equivocations demonstrate that he was no different than the other
Bolshevik leaders in government. But, after 1927, living in exile and no
longer having responsibility for managing the Soviet state, he could
delight in endlessly repeating the sacred principles of socialism. He
became like many academic Marxists who have the luxury of asserting
6 I M p e R I A LMI S
oMN TTHoLdy A R
ye V Ie W / J u Ly-Aug uST 2 0 1 56
A N e w S t a g e o f M o n o po l y C ap it a l
The contemporary world is still confronted with the same challenges
encountered by the revolutions of the twentieth century. The contin-
ued deepening of the center/periphery contrast, characteristic of the
spread of globalized capitalism, still leads to the same major political
consequence: transformation of the world begins with anti-imperialist,
national, popular—and potentially anti-capitalist—revolutions, which
are the only ones on the agenda for the foreseeable future. But this trans-
formation will only be able to go beyond the first steps and proceed on
the path to socialism later if and when the peoples of the centers, in turn,
begin the struggle for communism, viewed as a higher stage of universal
human civilization. The systemic crisis of capitalism in the centers gives
a chance for this possibility to be translated into reality.
In the meantime, there is a two-fold challenge confronting the
peoples and states of the South: (1) the lumpen development that
contemporary capitalism forces on all peripheries of the system has
nothing to offer to three-quarters of humanity; in particular, it leads
to the rapid destruction of peasant societies in Asia and Africa, and
consequently the response given to the peasant question will largely
govern the nature of future changes;7 (2) the aggressive geostrategy of
the imperialist powers, which is opposed to any attempt by the peoples
and states of the periphery to get out of the impasse, forces the peoples
concerned to defeat the military control of the world by the United
States and its subaltern European and Japanese allies.
The first long systemic crisis of capitalism got underway in
the 1870s. The version of historic capitalism’s extension over the
long span that I have put forward suggests a succession of three
epochs: ten centuries of incubation from the year 1000 in China to
the eighteenth-century revolutions in England and France, a short
century of triumphal flourishing (the nineteenth century), probably
a long decline comprising in itself the first long crisis (1875–1945) and
then the second (begun in 1975 and still ongoing). In each of those
two long crises, capital responds to the challenge by the same triple
formula: concentration of capital’s control, deepening of uneven
globalization, financialization of the system’s management.8 Two major
thinkers (Hobson and Hilferding) immediately grasped the enormous
importance of capitalism’s transformation into monopoly capitalism.
But it was Lenin and Bukharin who drew the political conclusion from
this transformation, a transformation that initiated the decline of
capitalism and thus moved the socialist revolution onto the agenda.9
8 I M p e R I A LMI S
oMN TTHoLdy A R
ye V Ie W / J u Ly-Aug uST 2 0 1 58
labor and unproductive labor. All forms of wage labor can—and do—
become sources of possible profits. A hairdresser sells his services to
a customer who pays him out of his income. But if that hairdresser
becomes the employee of a beauty parlor, the business must realize
a profit for its owner. If the country at issue puts ten million wage
workers to work in Departments I, II, and III, providing the equivalent
of twelve million years of abstract labor, and if the wages received
by those workers allow them to buy goods and services requiring
merely six million years of abstract labor, the rate of exploitation for
all of them, productive and unproductive confounded, is the same 100
percent. But the six million years of abstract labor that the workers do
not receive cannot all be invested in the purchase of producer goods
destined to the expansion of Departments I and II; part of them will
have to be put toward the expansion of Department III.
g e n e r al i zed -M o n o p o l y C ap i t al i s m (Sin c e 1 9 7 5 )
chains, to the point that the price structures forced on them wipe out
the income from their labor. Farmers survive only thanks to public
subsidies paid for by the taxpayers. This extraction is thus at the origin
of the monopolies’ profits! As likewise has been observed with bank
failures, the new principal of economic management is summed up in
a phrase: privatization of the monopolies’ profits, socialization of their
losses! To go on talking of “fair and open competition” and of “truth of
the prices revealed by the markets”—that belongs in a farce.
The fragmented, and by that fact concrete, economic power of propri-
etary bourgeois families gives way to a centralized power exercised by the
directors of the monopolies and their cohort of salaried servitors. For gen-
eralized-monopoly capitalism involves not the concentration of property,
which on the contrary is more dispersed than ever, but of the power to
manage it. That is why it is deceptive to attach the adjective “patrimonial”
to contemporary capitalism. It is only in appearance that “shareholders”
rule. Absolute monarchs, the top executives of the monopolies, decide
everything in their name. Moreover, the deepening globalization of the
system wipes out the holistic (i.e., simultaneously economic, political, and
social) logic of national systems without putting in its place any global
logic whatsoever. This is the empire of chaos—title of one of my works,
published in 1991 and subsequently taken up by others: in fact interna-
tional political violence takes the place of economic competition.12
F i n an c i a li z a t i o n o f Ac c u mu l a t i o n
T h e C o l l ect i v e I mp e r i a l is m o f t h e Tri a d ; t h e S t a t e in
C o n te mp o r a ry C ap i t al i s m
In the 1970s, Sweezy, Magdoff, and I had already advanced this
thesis, formulated by André Gunder Frank and me in a work published
12 I M p e R I A LMI S
oMN TTHoLdy A R
ye V Ie W / J u Ly-Aug uST 2 0 1 5 12
willingly accept the hierarchy that allows that alliance to function: gen-
eral leadership is taken on by Washington, and leadership in Europe by
Berlin. The national state remains in place to serve globalization as it is.
There is an idea circulating in postmodernist currents that contempo-
rary capitalism no longer needs the state to manage the world economy
and thus that the state system is in the process of withering away to
the benefit of the emergence of civil society. I will not go back over the
arguments that I have developed elsewhere against this naive thesis, one
moreover that is propagated by the dominant governments and the media
clergy in their service. There is no capitalism without the state. Capitalist
globalization could not be pursued without the interventions of the
United States armed forces and the management of the dollar. Clearly, the
armed forces and money are instruments of the state, not of the market.
But since there is no world state, the United States intends to fulfill
this function. The societies of the triad consider this function to be
legitimate; other societies do not. But what does that matter? The self-
proclaimed “international community,” i.e., the G7 plus Saudi Arabia,
which has surely become a democratic republic, does not recognize the
legitimacy of the opinion of 85 percent of the world’s population!
There is thus an asymmetry between the functions of the state in
the dominant imperialist centers and those of the state in the subject,
or yet to be subjected, peripheries. The state in the compradorized
peripheries is inherently unstable and, consequently, a potential
enemy, when it is not already one.
There are enemies with which the dominant imperialist powers have
been forced to coexist—at least up until now. This is the case with China
because it has rejected (up until now) the neo-comprador option and is
pursuing its sovereign project of integrated and coherent national develop-
ment. Russia became an enemy as soon as Putin refused to align politically
with the triad and wanted to block the expansionist ambitions of the lat-
ter in Ukraine, even if he does not envision (or not yet?) leaving the rut of
economic liberalism. The great majority of comprador states in the South
(that is, states in the service of their comprador bourgeoisies) are allies,
not enemies—as long as each of these comprador states gives the appear-
ance of being in charge of its country. But leaders in Washington, London,
Berlin, and Paris know that these states are fragile. As soon as a popular
movement of revolt—with or without a viable alternative strategy—threat-
ens one of these states, the triad arrogates to itself the right to intervene.
Intervention can even lead to contemplating the destruction of these states
and, beyond them, of the societies concerned. This strategy is currently
15 I M p e R I A LMI S
oMN TTHoLdy A R
ye V Ie W / J u Ly-Aug uST 2 0 1 5 15
at work in Iraq, Syria, and elsewhere. The raison d’être of the strategy for
military control of the world by the triad led by Washington is located
entirely in this “realist” vision, which is in direct counterpoint to the naive
view—à la Negri—of a globalized state in the process of formation.14
R e s p o n s e s o f t h e pe o p le s a n d S t a t e s o f t h e S o u t h
policy” is bound to fail if it is not supported by the Russian people. And this
support cannot be won on the exclusive basis of “nationalism.” The sup-
port can be won only if the internal economic and social policy pursued
promotes the interests of the majority of the working people. A people-
oriented policy implies therefore moving away, as much as possible,
from the “liberal” recipe and the electoral masquerade associated with
it, which claims to give legitimacy to regressive social policies. I would
suggest setting up in its place a brand of new state capitalism with a
social dimension (I say social, not socialist). That system would open the
road to eventual advances toward a socialization of the management of
the economy and therefore authentic new advances toward an invention
of democracy responding to the challenges of a modern economy.
Russian state power remaining within the strict limits of the
neoliberal recipe annihilates the chances of success of an independent
foreign policy and the chances of Russia becoming a really emerging
country acting as an important international actor. Neoliberalism can
produce for Russia only a tragic economic and social regression, a
pattern of “lumpen development” and a growing subordinate status
in the global imperialist order. Russia would provide to the Triad
oil, gas, and some other natural resources; its industries would be
reduced to the status of sub-contracting for the benefit of Western
financial monopolies. In such a position, which is not very far from that
of Russia today in the global system, attempts to act independently
in the international area will remain extremely fragile, threatened by
“sanctions” which will strengthen the disastrous alignment of the
ruling economic oligarchy to the demands of dominant monopolies of
the Triad. The current outflow of “Russian capital” associated with the
Ukraine crisis illustrates the danger. Reestablishing state control over
the movements of capital is the only effective response to that danger.
Outside of China, which is implementing a national project of
modern industrial development in connection with the renovation
of family agriculture, the other so-called emergent countries of the
South (the BRICS) still walk only on one leg: they are opposed to the
depredations of militarized globalization, but remain imprisoned in
the straightjacket of neoliberalism.18
N o t es
1. In this article, I am limiting myself to 2. Before the Second World War, Stalin Cold War, while Stalin sought to extend
examining the experiences of Russia and had desperately, and unsuccessfully, friendship with the Western powers,
China, with no intention of ignoring the sought an alliance with the Western again without success. See Geoffrey
other twentieth-century socialist democracies against Nazism. After the Roberts, Stalin’s Wars: From World War to
revolutions (North Korea, Vietnam, Cuba). war, Washington chose to pursue the Cold War, 1939–1953 (New Haven, CT:
17 I M p e R I A LMI S
oMN TTHoLdy A R
ye V Ie W / J u Ly-Aug uST 2 0 1 5 17
Yale University Press, 2007). See the 8. I discuss here only some of the major Bandung 2015, (Paris, 2014). NEED
important preface by Annie Lacroix Riz to consequences of the move to generalized ACTUAL DAYS?
the French edition: Les guerres de monopolies (financialization, decline of 14. “Contra Hardt and Negri,” Monthly Re-
Staline: De la guerre mondiale à la guerre democracy). As for ecological questions, I view 66, no. 6 (November 2014): 25–36.
froide (Paris: Éditions Delga, 2014). refer to the remarkable works of John
Bellamy Foster. 15. The choice to delink is inevitable. The
3. I am alluding here to Kautsky’s theses extreme centralization of the surplus at
in The Agrarian Question, 2 vols. (London: 9. Nicolai Bukharin, Imperialism and the the world level in the form of imperialist
Pluto Press, 1988; first edition, 1899). World Economy (New York: Monthly Re- rent for the monopolies of the imperialist
4. There are pleasant exceptions among view Press, 1973; written in 1915); V. I. powers is unsupportable by all societies
Marxist intellectuals who, without having Lenin, Imperialism, The Highest Stage of in the periphery. It is necessary to
had responsibilities in the leadership of Capitalism (New York: International Pub- deconstruct this system with the prospect
revolutionary parties or, still less, of lishers, 1969; written in 1916). of reconstructing it later in another form
revolutionary states, have nonetheless 10. For further discussions of the Depart- of globalization compatible with
remained attentive to the challenges ment III analysis and its relation to Baran communism understood as a more
confronted by state socialisms (I am and Sweezy’s theory of surplus absorp- advanced stage of universal civilization. I
thinking here of Baran, Sweezy, tion see Samir Amin, Three Essays on have suggested, in this context, a
Hobsbawn, and others). Marx’s Value Theory (New York: Monthly comparison with the necessary
5. See Samir Amin, “China 2013,” Month- Review Press, 2013), 67–76; and John destruction of the centralization of the
ly Review 64, no. 10 (March 2013): 14– Bellamy Foster, “Marxian Crisis Theory Roman Empire, which opened the way to
33, in particular for analyses concerning and the State,” in John Bellamy Foster feudal decentralization.
Maoism’s treatment of the agrarian ques- and Henryk Szlajfer, eds., The Faltering 16. Yash Tandon, Trade is War (OR Books,
tion. Economy (New York: Monthly Review forthcoming).
Press, 1984), 325–49.
6. See Eric J. Hobsbawn, Echoes of the 17. Samir Amin, “Russia in the World Sys-
Marseillaise: Two Centuries Look Back on 11. Andre Gunder Frank and Samir Amin, tem,” chapter 7 in Global History: A View
the French Revolution (London: Verso, “Let’s Not Wait for 1984,” in Frank, from the South (London: Pambazuka
1990); also see the works of Florence Reflections on the World Economic Crisis Press, 2010, “The Return of Fascism in
Gauthier. These authors do not assimilate (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1981). Contemporary Capitalism,” Monthly Re-
Thermidor to restoration, as the Trotskyist 12. Samir Amin, Empire of Chaos (New view 66, no. 4 (September 2014): 1–12.
simplification suggests. York: Monthly Review Press, 1992). 18. Concerning the inadequate respons-
7. Concerning the destruction of the 13. Concerning the challenge to financial es of India and Brazil, see “Emergence
Asian and African peasantry currently un- globalizaton, see Samir Amin, “The and Lumpen Development,” chapter 2 in
derway, see Samir Amin, “Contemporary Chinese Yuan” (published in Chinese, my The Implosion of Capitalism (New
Imperialism and the Agrarian Question,” 2013); Samir Amin, “From Bandung York: Monthly Review Press, 2013), as
Agrarian South: Journal of Political Econo- (1955) to 2015: New and Old Challenges well as “Latin America Confronts the
my 1, no. 1 (April 2012): 11–26, http:// for the Peoples and States of the South,” Challenge of Globalization,” Monthly Re-
ags.sagepub.com. paper presented at the conference view 66, no. 7 (December 2014): 1–6.