Bepmc 311 Module 3-A
Bepmc 311 Module 3-A
Bepmc 311 Module 3-A
We extend the analysis of demand and supply by looking at how consumers and producers
respond to changes in price by examining the concept of elasticity. These concepts will be further
used to examine the effect of taxes on prices and quantities consumed and produced. Lastly, we also
extend demand and supply concepts to evaluate consumers and producers welfare using the concept
of consumer surplus and producer surplus.
At the end of this module, you should have achieved the following topic or unit learning
outcomes.
Describe demand and supply concepts and how these forces determine and affect equilibrium
price and quantity.
Graphically illustrate the effect of change in demand and/or supply on market equilibrium.
Demonstrate how elasticities of demand and supply are calculated and interpreted.
TOPIC 1: DEMAND
DEFINITION
We note, first and foremost, that demand manifests consumers’ (buyers’) willingness and
ability to buy. This means that consumers are willing to buy because they have the desire to have the
product and at the same time they have the money (purchasing power) to buy the product. Second,
demand for a good is time-bounded. Demand happens at a given period of time, it can be in a day, a
month, a quarter of a year, in one year, and so on.
Demand for a good (or service) at a given time depends on many factors (price, technology,
competition, etc.). However, if other factors (also called non-price determinants) are held constant (or
not changing) at a given time, the quantity (amount) of a good that sellers are willing to sell becomes
a function of or depends on the price of the good. Based from this principle, a demand schedule (a
table that shows the quantity supplied at each price) can be illustrated.
We assume that the buyer has money worth P100 and only used to buy good X. If we assume
prices of good X, the amounts the buyer can buy can be determined.
What explains the law of demand? (i.e., why is it that price and quantity demanded are
negatively related)? There are two basic reasons for this relationship:
There are two views of income: nominal income and real income. Nominal ( or money) income
is the value or amount of income received. For example, an individual receives P10,000 this
month. Real income reflects the purchasing power of the nominal income, i.e., how much goods
and services that money income of P10,000 buy. The income effect tells us that as the P of a
good falls, the Qd rises because the purchasing power of the same nominal income the individual
has increases allowing more amounts to be purchased a P falls.
The substitution effect on the other hand, tells us that as the P of a good rises, Qd falls because
the consumer has this tendency to substituted other goods that are now relatively cheaper
compared to the good which increased in P.
Diminishing – decreasing
Utility – satisfaction
Marginal – extra, added, additional
Marginal utility – the extra satisfaction derived from consuming extra unit of the same
good
The law of diminishing marginal utility states that all else equal, as the consumption (Qd) of a
good increases the marginal utility derived from each additional unit declines. What decreases as
additional unit of the same good is consumed is the extra (or added) satisfaction. As more units
of the same good is consumed, it means that the extra satisfaction we derived will eventually
diminish. Since the extra utility diminishes as more unit of the same good is consumed,
consumers tend to place a lower value (the price) on the good. Therefore, the only way to
increase Qd (or entice consumers to buy more units of the same despite diminished marginal
utility) is for P to fall.
DEMAND CURVE
Market demand is derived by summing up all the individual demands for a good. Market
supply is simply the horizontal summation (summation of all quantities demanded by all buyers
at each possible price) of all individual demand.
PX D’
D
D” There are more
quantities
demanded at each
Increase in Demand possible price than
There are less in the previous
quantities time-period
demanded at each Decrease in Demand
possible price
than in the
previous time-
period
QdX
Figure 3: Shifts in Demand Curve
There are many variables that can shift the supply curve. Here are some of the most
important.
2. Number of Buyers
An increase in the number of buyers in a market is likely to increase product demand; a decrease
in the number of buyers will probably decrease demand. For example, a rising number of older
persons will increase the demand for medical care, and retirement communities. In contrast,
emigration (out-migration) from many small rural communities has reduced the population and
thus the demand for housing, home appliances, and auto repair in those towns.
3. Income
How changes in income affect demand is a more complex matter. For most products, a rise in
income causes an increase in demand. Products whose demand varies directly with money
income are called superior goods, or normal goods. Although most products are normal goods,
there are some exceptions. As incomes increase beyond some point, the demand for used
clothing, retread tires, and third-hand automobiles may decrease, because the higher incomes
enable consumers to buy new versions of those products. Goods whose demand varies inversely
with money income are called inferior goods.
4. Prices of Related Goods
A change in the price of a related good may either increase or decrease the demand for a product,
depending on whether the related good is a substitute or a complement:
A substitute good is one that can be used in place of another good. Also, goods are
substitutes when the price of one good is positively related to the demand for the other good.
(For example, pork and chicken are substitutes; an increase in the price of pork will reduce its
quantity demanded, therefore those who will reduce its quantity demand for pork will shift to
chicken causing the demand for chicken to increase.
A complementary good is one that is used together with another good. Also, two goods are
complements when the price of one good is inversely related to the demand for the other
good. For example, if the price of coffee increases, quantity demanded will decrease,
therefore who cuts down consumption of coffee will find themselves reducing consumption
of creamer causing the demand for creamer to decrease.
5. Consumer Expectations
Changes in consumer expectations may shift demand. A newly formed expectation of higher
future prices may cause consumers to buy now in order to “beat” the anticipated price rises, thus
in- creasing current demand. Similarly, a change in expectations concerning future income may
prompt consumers to change their current spending. For example, workers who become fearful
of losing their jobs may reduce their demand for, say, vacation travel.
DEMAND FUNCTION
Demand function is the mathematical expression of law of demand. In other words, demand
function quantifies the relationship between quantity demanded and price of a product, while keeping
the other factors at constant. The law of demand expresses the nature of relationship between quantity
demanded and price of a product, while the demand function measures that relationship.
The demand function can be expressed in two ways: (1) as a quantity function: QD = f(P) or,
(2) as a price-function: P = f(QD). Note however, that even if a demand function can be expressed in
two ways, they still represent one demand curve.
We now quantify the law of demand by expressing the demand function in terms of a linear
equation: y = mx + b (y = a + bx)
y 2− y 1
Using two-point form formula: y− y1 = ( x−x 1)
x2 − x1
Example: Given the data below, determine the demand function, interpret the slope and the vertical
intercept, and graph the full demand curve.
Q−60= ( 50−60
10−8 )
P−8 Q−60= (−102 ) P−8
Q−60=−5 P+ 40 Q = –5P + 40 + 60 Q = –5P + 100
P−8= ( 50−60
10−8
) Q−60 P−8= (−102 )Q−60
P−8=−0.2Q+12 P = –0.2Q + 12 + 8 P = –0.2Q + 20
TOPIC 2: SUPPLY
A market is not complete without the other side of it. We now turn to the other side of the
market and examine the behavior of sellers.
DEFINITION
We begin by defining the term supply. Supply is technically defined as a curve (or can be a
schedule or an equation) which shows the various amounts of a product that producers (sellers) are
willing and able to make available for sale at each of a series of possible prices, during some specified
period of time.
We note, first and foremost, that supply manifests producers’ (sellers’) willingness and ability
to produce or sell. This means that producers (sellers) are willing because they are profit-motivated,
aside from a good or service is demand-driven (there are willing consumers to pay for the good (or
service). Producers (sellers) are also able (capacity) to produce (sell) because they have the resources.
Supply for a good is time-bounded. Supply happens at a given period of time, it can be in a
day, a month, a quarter of a year, in one year, and so on. Just as demand for a good is realized on a
specific time-period, so is the supply for a good.
Supply for a good (or service) at a given time depends on many factors (price, technology,
competition, etc.). However, if other factors (also called non-price determinants) are held constant (or
not changing) at a given time, the quantity (amount) of a good that sellers are willing to sell becomes
a function of or depends on the price of the good. Based from this principle, a supply schedule (a table
that shows the quantity supplied at each price) can be illustrated:
Table 3: Supply of Rice, Benguet, 2006-2016
Year Price (average, Production (Metric
annual per kg) Tons) Quantity supplied
2006 P19.99 10,248.00
2007 20.81 10,921.00
2008 29.05 11,142.00
2009 29.69 11,244.00
2010 29.72 11,357.00
2011 29.92 11,363.50
2012 30.00 11,402.40
2013 30.80 11,569.15
2014 38.89 11,780.75
2015 39.64 11,793.60
2016 39.95 11,794.25
Source: PSA (Philippine Statistics Authority), Rice Statistics
LAW OF SUPPLY
The amount of a good that producers are willing to sell at a given price is called the quantity
supplied (QS). There are many determinants of QS, but price (P) plays a special role in analyzing
producers’ (suppliers’) behavior. As seen in the schedule, as the average price per kg of rice rises
overtime, production (quantity supplied, in metric tons) also increase. This relationship between price
and quantity supplied is called the law of supply: Other things equal, when the price of a good rises,
the quantity supplied of the good also rises, and when the price falls, the quantity supplied falls as
well. The curve showing the relationship between price and quantity supplied is the supply curve.
Just as market demand is the sum of the demands of all buyers, market supply is the sum of
the supplies of all sellers. Market supply is horizontal summation (summation of all quantities
supplied by all sellers at each possible price) of all individual supply.
Figure 6: Individual Supply and Market Supply
Because the market supply curve holds other things constant at a given period of time, a
change in supply or a shift in the supply curve is caused by a change in one or more of the non-price
determinants (or other factors) that affect the quantity supplied for a good. When a change in supply
occurs, it happens at a new time period and is compared to the supply at a previous time period.
Graphically:
PX S”
There are less Decrease in Supply S
quantities supplied S’
at each possible
price than in the
previous time-
period
There are more
Increase in Supply quantities supplied
at each possible
price than in the
previous time-
period.
QSX
Figure 7: Shifts in Supply Curve
There are many variables that can shift the supply curve. Here are some of the most
important.
1. Input prices. Firms use a number of different inputs to produce any kind of good or service (i.e.
output). When the prices of those inputs increase, the firms face higher production costs. As a
result, producing said good or service becomes less profitable and firms will reduce supply. That
is the supply curve shifts to the left (i.e. inward). By contrast, a decrease in input prices reduces
production costs and therefore shifts the supply curve to the right (i.e. outward).
2. Technology. The use of advanced technology in the production process increases productivity,
which makes the production of goods or services more profitable. As a result, the supply curve
shifts right, i.e. supply increases. Please note that technology in the context of the production
process usually only causes an increase in supply, but not a decrease. The reason for this is
simple: new technology is only adopted if it increases productivity. Otherwise, sellers can just
stick with the technology they already have, which does not affect productivity (and thus supply).
3. Number of Sellers. The number of sellers in a market has a significant impact on supply. When
more firms enter a market to sell a specific good or service, supply increases. That is the supply
curve shifts to the right. Meanwhile, when firms exit the market, supply decreases, i.e. the supply
curve shifts to the left.
4. Producers’ Expectations. The seller’s expectations of the future have a significant impact on
supply. Or more specifically, their expectations of future prices and/or other factors that affect
supply. If they expect prices to increase in the near future, they will hold some of their output
back (i.e. reduce current supply) in order to increase supply in the future, when it becomes more
profitable.
5. Taxes and Subsidies. Part of a firm’s cost of production is tax. Business tax is not directly part
of producing a good or service, as it is not an input cost. However, as government mandates all
firms to pay the tax, it does add to total cost of production. Therefore, an increase in business
taxes collected by government will increase the total cost of production, firms supply less of a
good than a previous time period (where business taxes are still low), causing the supply curve to
shift to the left. On the other hand, subsidies are taxes on reverse (i.e., there are financial aids or
grants to firms by the government). With more subsidies coming from the government, firms can
lower down costs, then more will be supplied at the current time than in the previous time period.
6. Natural and Social Factors. There are always a number of natural and social factors that affect
supply. They can either affect how much output sellers can produce or how much they want to
produce. Whenever one of those factors causes supply to decrease, the supply curve shifts to the
left, whereas an increase in supply results in a shift to the right. As a rule of thumb, natural
factors generally affect how much sellers can produce, while social factors have a greater effect
on how much they want to produce.
Examples of natural factors that affect supply include natural disasters, pestilence, diseases, or
extreme weather conditions. Basically, anything that can have an effect on inputs or facilities that
are required in the production process. Meanwhile, examples of social factors include increased
demand for organic products, waste disposal requirements, minimum wage laws, other
government regulations (e.g., environmental compliance, quota). Note that not all of those factors
necessarily have an impact on the cost of production, but all of them affect production decisions.
SUPPLY FUNCTION
Supply function is the mathematical expression of law of supply. In other words, supply
function quantifies the relationship between quantity supplied and price of a product, while keeping
the other factors at constant. The law of supply expresses the nature of relationship between quantity
supplied and price of a product, while the supply function measures that relationship.
The supply function can be expressed in two ways: (1) as a quantity function: QS = f(P) or, (2)
as a price-function: P = f(QS). Note however, that even if a supply function can be expressed in two
ways, they still represent one supply curve.
We now quantify the law of supply by expressing the supply function in terms of a linear
equation: y = mx + b
Determining a linear equation can be done by algebraic solution applying the following
formulae:
y 2− y 1
Using two-point form formula: y− y1 = ( x−x 1)
x2− x1
Example: Consider the data below on price and quantity supplied. Determine the supply function.
Interpret the slope and intercept of the supply function. Graph the supply curve.
Solution
1. Supply function: Q-function
Q−500= ( 600−500
9−7 )
P−7 Q−500= ( 1002 ) P−7
Q−500=50 P−350 Q = 50P – 350 + 500 Q = 50P + 150
P−7= ( 600−500
9−7
) Q−500 P−7= ( 1002 )Q−500
P−7=0.02 Q−10 P = 0.02Q – 10 + 7 P = 0.02Q – 3
2. Interpretation:
Interpreting the quantity function: Q = 50P + 150
Slope m = 50 (units): for every P1 change (increase or decrease) in price, quantity supplied
will change (increase or decrease) by 50 units
Vertical intercept b = 150 (units): if P = P0, the minimum amount to be given away for free
is 150 units
3. Supply curve
Equilibrium is an ideal state of rest or balance, once achieved it tends to persist. When one is
at the equilibrium then no force exists that will move one away from the equilibrium. When buyers
and sellers meet in the market to exchange goods and services, they carry with them their own self-
interest. A buyer wants a lower price as much as possible and a seller wants a higher price as much as
possible. These are conflicting interests and how are they reconciled? Or how does the market attain
equilibrium?
Once buyers and sellers “agree” on the price of a good or service in the market, equilibrium is
achieved. The price is called equilibrium price or market-clearing price. This price is now acceptable
to both buyers and sellers, and as long as no other factors will change to cause a change in this price,
this condition remains in the market.
Putting together the demand and supply curves in the same graph, equilibrium occurs where
the demand and supply curves intersect. Formally, this occurs at the price where quantity demanded
(Qd) equals quantity supplied (Qs)
Although this is the equilibrium in the demand and supply model, it remains important to
understand why it is the equilibrium. That is, how does the equilibrium meet the characteristics
defined above that must exist for something to be a stable equilibrium? We must essentially show that
the equilibrium has three characteristics:
1. When the actual price exceeds the equilibrium price some force exists that moves the market
back to the equilibrium price. In the figure below, suppose that the actual price, at P2, in the
market exceeds the equilibrium price, PE. This means, first of all, that the quantity demanded
(QD) no longer equals the quantity supplied (QS).
Figure 10: Disequilibrium: Surplus
Recall that QD is given by the demand curve at the given price. Likewise, QS is given by the
supply curve at the given price. Hence, when price equals P2, then QD will equal Q1 and QS will
equal Q2; quantity supplied is more than quantity demanded. This result is known as an excess
supply or a surplus.
When a surplus occurs that means that firms are unable to do what they desire in the market
given the price. Given a price of P2, firms produce and would like to sell a quantity of Q2, but can
only actually find buyers for a quantity of Q1. The difference between the two equals the actual
surplus. Notice, however, that consumers can do what they wish in the market given the price.
How do firms and consumers respond when faced with a surplus? Given that consumers can
already buy as much as they wish in the market given the price, they do not change their
behavior. Firms, on the other hand, cannot sell all of the output that they produce. Left with
unsold inventory, firms respond by attempting to sell that inventory. How do they induce
consumers to buy their production, rather than their competitors? The most basic way to do so is
by offering the product to consumers at a lower price. However, such price competition by firms
will continue as long as any surplus exists. As a result, the price will decrease until the surplus
dissipates. Thus, the force that causes the price to fall back to the equilibrium when a surplus
exists is price competition by that sector of the market that cannot do what it wishes at the market
price, in this case firms.
2. When the actual price is less than the equilibrium price some force exists that moves the market
back to the equilibrium price. In the graph below, suppose that the actual price, at P1 in the
market is less than the equilibrium price, PE. This means, first of all, that the quantity demanded
(QD) no longer equals the quantity supplied (Q S). When the price equals P1, then QD will equal Q2
and QS will equal Q1; quantity demanded is more than quantity supplied. This result is known as
an excess demand or a shortage.
When a shortage occurs, consumers are unable to do what they desire in the market, given the
price. Given that firms can already sell as much as they want at the price, firms will not change
their behavior at the given price. However, consumers cannot buy all of the good they want at the
current price. Faced with unmet demand, consumers respond by all of them attempting to buy the
limited quantity available for sale. How do consumers induce firms to sell their limited
production to them? Again, the most basic method, which is consistent with profit-maximization,
is for consumers to offer to pay higher prices. However, such price competition, this time by
consumers, will continue as long as the shortage exists. Thus, the price will continue to increase
until the shortage completely disappears.
Although it is price competition, just as when a surplus exists, that forces the market to move
back to the equilibrium, in this case it is by consumers and not firms.
3. When the actual price equals the equilibrium price no force exists that moves the market away
from the equilibrium price.
Figure 12: Natural Tendency to Equilibrium
Thus, price competition only exists when one of the actors in the market is dissatisfied, when
they either cannot sell or buy all that they desire at the market price. But at the equilibrium price
and quantity of PE and QE in Figure 2:11, both firms’ and consumers’ desires are being met
exactly because quantity demanded equals quantity supplied. The fact that there exists neither a
surplus nor a shortage means that no price competition will form moving the market away from
the equilibrium.
Thus, as shown in Figure 2.12, both of the requirements for a stable equilibrium are met – when
not at the equilibrium some force, price competition, moves the market back to equilibrium and
when at the equilibrium the price competition does not form, keeping the market at the
equilibrium. Although the force in the demand and supply model moving the market to
equilibrium is price competition, students often have difficulty remembering which actor is
competing. To understand this point, just ask who it is that doesn’t get to do what they desire at
the current market price. That will be the party who changes their behavior and competes in an
attempt to reach a desirable outcome. Clearly, the party who has already attained his desires
given the situation in the market will not change her behavior in order to compete.
The main purpose of the demand and supply model is to be able to make predictions about the
impact of a given change in the market upon equilibrium price and quantity. These predictions depend
upon the following steps:
1. Identify exactly the impact upon the given market. (That is, which market is being
impacted and by what event?)
2. Does the change affect demand, supply, or both?
3. In which direction is demand or supply affected?
4. What happens to equilibrium price and quantity as a result?
For example, if the price of wheat increases, what impact will this have upon the market for
bread? Wheat is an input into the production of bread. Hence, the supply of bread will be affected
because supply deals with production. Recall from our discussion of demand and supply in the
previous chapter that when input prices increase, the costs of production are in turn increased, which
decreases the supply of the good, in this case bread. What is the impact on equilibrium price and
quantity? The specific impact is discussed separately for each of eight different possible scenarios
below. These will focus on answering only the last of the four questions above – what happens to
equilibrium price and quantity for a given change in demand or supply. As a student, you should be
prepared to answer the other three questions as well.
Increase in Demand
However, when the demand increases (shifts right) at a price of P 1 the market is no longer
in equilibrium. Rather, a shortage or excess demand now exists. As discussed above, when a
shortage occurs price competition by consumers forces the price to rise to a new
equilibrium, E2, where the new equilibrium price and quantity equal P 2 and Q2
respectively. Notice that this process of price competition does cause us to move to the
equilibrium.
The end result is that both equilibrium price and quantity increase.
Decrease in Demand
In addition to the above type of question, students should be prepared to ask more difficult
questions; questions that rely upon them correctly working through all four of the steps discussed
above. Consider, for example, the following question:
Suppose that the price of gas increases. What impact, if any, will this change have upon the
market for cars?
In order to answer this question, you must decide which will be affected, demand or supply.
Be careful, it’s possible that neither will be affected, in which case the correct answer is A. Recall,
that cars and gasoline are complements in consumption. Since demand is related to consumption, it is
the demand curve that will be affected and not the supply curve. Likewise, since complementary
goods are those that are consumed together, when the price of gas increases, people will buy less gas
(law of demand). However, with lower use of gas also comes less demand for cars. As a result, the
demand for cars will fall. As shown by Figure 2.14, when the demand for a good falls, then the
equilibrium price and quantity of that good will also fall. Hence, choice C is the correct answer.
It is possible for both demand and supply to be affected simultaneously in the real world. As a
result, it is useful to be able to make predictions about what will happen in a market when such a
result occurs. For example, suppose that some change occurs in the market for gasoline that
induces both consumers and firms to expect that the price of gas will rise in the future.
Recall that an expected higher price will induce consumers to buy more of the good now since it
is cheaper now than it is expected to be in the future. Hence, demand for gas now will increase.
Likewise, an expected higher future price will induce suppliers to sell less of the good now since
its relatively cheaper price is less attractive to profit maximizing firms than the future expected
higher price. Hence, supply for gas now will decrease.
This result, however, is somewhat deceptive. Notice that, as discussed above, the result of a
decrease in Supply (Figure 2.16) is to increase price and decrease quantity while the result of an
increase in demand (Figure 2.13) is to increase both price and quantity. Clearly, because the
changes in both demand and supply curves cause price to increase, then price will increase.
However, each shift has an opposite impact on equilibrium quantity. The supply shift decreases
quantity, while the demand shift increases quantity. Figure 2.17 illustrates the result that occurs if
these two opposing impacts on quantity exactly cancel each other out. This only occurs when the
two shifts are of the same magnitude. However, it is just as possible that quantity could increase
(demand shift larger) or decrease (supply shift larger). Without information about the magnitude
of the two shifts we simply cannot determine what will happen to quantity.
This discussion highlights an important point about simultaneous shifts of both supply and
demand. In each of the four cases discussed below, either equilibrium price or quantity will be
indeterminate without information about the magnitude of the shifts. However, simply drawing a
graph as we did above with only a single shift of a single curve, leads one to misleading
conclusions without that information. This is because when drawing such a shift on a graph one
must make an assumption about the relative magnitudes of the two shifts. As a result, it is
actually more useful to not draw any additional graphs. Instead, simply look at the four graphs
that we’ve already discussed above and consider the impact of each shift separately.
We will now combine the knowledge we gained about linear demand and linear supply
equations to figure out how to determine the equilibrium price and quantity in the market using the
demand and supply equations.
The equilibrium condition states that at a certain price (i.e., equilibrium price), QS = QD.
Following this condition, we just equate the determined demand and supply equations. For example:
Consider the market for shoes. The linear demand and supply functions are:
QD = 250 – 10P
QS = 50 + 10P
P = 10 equilibrium price
Solve for equilibrium quantity by substituting the value of price on demand/supply equations:
At equilibrium price, QS = QD
QS = 150 QD = 150
By tabular solution, we will arrive at the same values of equilibrium price and equilibrium.
Set up a demand and supply schedules.
A gap means an existence of either a surplus (QS > QD) or a shortage (QD > QS). A negative
value of the gap means shortage and a positive value of gap means surplus. Only at equilibrium where
gap is equal to zero. The equilibrium condition can also be illustrated using a graphical presentation.