Intermediate Microeconomics Answer
Intermediate Microeconomics Answer
Intermediate Microeconomics Answer
Economic Models
A. Summary
This chapter provides a methodological introduction to the book by showing
why economists use simplified models. The chapter begins with a few
definitions of economics and then turns to a discussion of economic models.
Development of Marshall's analysis of supply and demand is the principle
example of such a model here, and this provides a review for students of what
they learned in introductory economics. The notion of how shifts in supply or
demand curves affect equilibrium prices is highlighted and is repeated in the
chapters appendix in a somewhat more formal way. The chapter also reminds
students of the production possibility frontier concept and shows how it
illustrates opportunity costs. The chapter concludes with a discussion of how
economic models might be verified. A brief description of the distinction
between positive and normative analysis is also presented.
APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 1
Mathematics Used in
Microeconomics
A. Summary
This appendix provides a review of basic algebra with a specific focus on the
graphical tools that students will encounter later in the text. The coverage of
linear and quadratic equations here is quite standard and should be familiar to
students. Two concepts that will be new to some students are graphing contour
lines and simultaneous equations. The discussion of contour lines seeks to
introduce students to the indifference curve concept through the contour map
analogy.
Although students may not have graphed such a family of curves for a
many-variable function before, this introduction seems to provide good
preparation for the economic applications that follow.
The analysis of simultaneous equations presented in the appendix is
intended to illustrate how the solution to two linear equations in two unknowns
is reflected graphically by the intersection of the two lines. Although students
may be familiar with solving simultaneous equations through substitution or
subtraction, this graphical approach may not be so well known. Because such
graphic solutions lead directly to the economic concept of supply-demand
equilibrium, however, I believe it is useful to introduce this method of solution
to students. Showing how a shift in one of the equations changes the solutions
for both variables is particularly instructive in that regard. In that regard, some
material at the end of the appendix makes the distinction between endogenous
and exogenous variables a distinction that many students stumble over.
The appendix also contains a few illustrations of calculus-type results.
Depending on student preparation, instructors might wish to pick up on this
and use a few calculus ideas in later chapters. But this is not a calculus-based
text, so there is no need to do this.
Functional Notation
Independent Variable
Intercept
Linear Function
Marginal Effect
Simultaneous Equations
Slope
Statistical Inference
Variables
a.
b.
Yes, the points seem to be on straight lines. For the demand curve: P = 1
Q = 100
Q
100
at P 1, Q 700, so a 8 and
Q
P 8
or Q 800 100 P
100
Pa
For the supply curve, the points also seem to be on a straight line:
P
1
Q 200
If P a bQ a
Q
200
Q
or Q 200 P 100
200
1.2
a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
f.
g.
h.
i.
1.3
a. Excess Demand is the following at the various prices
Q 300 PS 2 PD 5
Q 500 PS 3 PD 3
Q 700 PS 4 PD 1
c. Many callout auctions operate this way though usually quantity supplied is a fixed
amount. Many financial markets operate with bid and asked prices which approximate
the procedure in part b.
1.4
P
10
S
D
4
10
c. The following figure graphs the demand and supply curves with P on the
horizontal axis. Solution proceeds as in Part b.
Q
10
S
4
D
2
10
d.
The equations can be graphed either way and will yield the same solution.
e.
Reasons for preferring one over the other are not readily apparent in these
drawings. As we shall see, however, developing demand and supply curves from
their underlying theoretical foundations does provide some rationale for Marshalls
choice.
1.5
QD = 2P + 20.
QS = 2P 4.
Set QD = QS: 2P + 20 = 2P 4
24 = 4P
P = 6.
Substituting for P gives: QD = QS = 8.
b.
Now QD = 2P + 24.
Set QD = QS: 2P + 24 = 2P 4
28 = 4P
P = 7.
Substituting gives: QD = QS = 10.
1.6
c.
P = 8, Q = 8 (see graph)
a.
T = .01 I 2
I = 10, T = .01(10) 2 = 1
2
Taxes = $1,000
I = 30, T = .01(30) = 9
Taxes = $9,000
I = 50, T = .01(50) 2 = 25
Taxes = $25,000
I = 100, T = 100.
b.
I = 10,000
I = 30,000
I = 50,000
Average Rate
10%
30%
50%
Marginal Rate
20%
60%
100%
c.
I
10,000
1,000
10,001
1,000.20
30,000
9,000
30,001
9,000.60
50,000
25,000
50,001
1.7
1.8
25,001
1.00
a.
b.
c.
d.
a.
If Y = 0, X = 10
If X= 0, Y = 5
b.
24
4
6
2
21
4
X
Y
The opportunity cost depends on the levels of output because the slope of a
curve is not constant.
d.
10
When X0 = 3,Y0 =
When X1 = 4,Y1 =
[Y1 Y0] = .187
9
21
a.
X2 + 4Y2 = 100
If X = Y, then 5X2 = 100 and X =
20 and Y =
20 .
b.
c.
d.
20 = 5 2
1.10
11
b.
c.
None of the other points on the Y = 4 contour line obey the linear equation. This
is so because the contour line is convex and hits the straight line at only a single
tangency.
d.
e.
Yes, many points on the line X 4 Z 10 provide a higher value for Y (any
points between the two identified in part d do). The largest value for Y is at the
point X = 5, Z = 5/4. In this case Y = 25/4 = 6.25.
f.