Harvesting Dispair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Harvesting Dispair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Harvesting Dispair: Agrarian Crisis in India
DESPAIR
PERSPECTIVES
January 2009
homicide, not suicide
Ramdas has an old and gnarled babul tree in the courtyard of his
home. A dilapidated mud hut with a roof of black plastic sheets. A
small courtyard surrounded by a boundary wall made of thorns
and wood. Three acres of land in Bharumri village in Yavatmal
district, Vidarbha. At the end of our hour-long conversation, Ramdas
pointed towards the babul tree and said, “Madam ji, when there is
no other option left for me, this will still be an option…”
When Ramdas and thousands of farmers like him across the country
decide to exercise their last option – end their own lives – it does not
make much news. People in the cities do not come out on the streets
asking why so many farmers have committed suicides in the last
fifteen years. Ministers of the state and central government do not
acknowledge their mistakes or policy failures and resign from office.
When an economic activity which provides livelihood to more than
five out of ten people suffers from stagnation and crisis, the
government does not announce crores of rupees of stimulus
packages, interest rate cuts, and daily assurances. Newspapers and
television channels do not scream for help and demand immediate
bailouts. There is so much brouhaha over the global financial crisis
in India, but hardly anyone seems bothered about the agrarian crisis
which has killed, on an average, one farmer every half hour in 2007
alone. After all, it is not the Sensex, banks or companies whose
survival is threatened. It is a question of survival for merely half the
population of our country. The population which remains invisible
in the villages, mandis and fields. The population which feeds the
country but is uncertain of its own future.
We, at Perspectives, started thinking about agriculture when we
were struggling with our earlier work – development and
displacement. The forced acquisition of agricultural land along with
lack of alternative employment opportunities for those displaced
made us think about the plight of those dependent on this sector. In
our opinion, no meaningful development of the economy is possible
without the growth and development of the agricultural sector.
In June 2007, a Perspectives team went to Mansa and Patiala districts
of Punjab. The myth of the unending prosperity of Green Revolution
was busted. The misery of farmers in one of the richest states of our
country convinced us that this was a matter worth investigating
and understanding. In May 2008, a team of seventeen people from
Perspectives visited the Pandharkawada tehsil of Yavatmal district,
one of the suicide-hit districts of Maharashtra. We interviewed
farmers in fifteen villages, some families where members had
committed suicides, and the peasant leaders of the region.
The desolation and hopelessness of Vidarbha farmers continues to
haunt us. The grim situation in Vidarbha galvanized us to
understand the complex causes of the larger crisis in Indian
agriculture. Suicides are only the proverbial tip of the iceberg. The
agrarian crisis in India has been deliberately engineered by the state,
to serve profit-seeking interests and to pursue the urban-centric,
growth-obsessed model of development. Credit to agriculture, public
investment, irrigation, subsidies, costs of inputs, minimum support,
public procurement, technology, trade-related international
agreements – the list of areas where governments could have acted
in the interest of our farmers, but chose to do the contrary, goes on and
on. During the course of our work, we have realised how much the
rulers of this country have neglected the agricultural sector,
especially in the period of liberalisation, privatisation and
globalisation, and made it possible for transnational corporations
of the developed countries to earn profits from this sector. They
have ensured that the occupation of agriculture loses all dignity and
respect, becomes unviable and unsustainable, and leaves the farmer
with no option but to seek ways – including suicide – to get out of
his profession.
We have divided the book into ten chapters. The first chapter
describes our experience of Vidarbha, our study and the analysis
and conclusions that follow from it. The second chapter introduces
the larger agrarian crisis and gives a historical overview of policies
and approach of the state towards agriculture. Chapters three, four
and five discuss policies at the domestic and international level
related to agriculture and their impact, especially during the period
of liberalisation, privatisation and globalisation. Credit policy
reforms, agricultural subsidies, public investment in agriculture,
costs of cultivation, market and procurement policies, and the
Agreement on Agriculture are discussed in these chapters. The sixth
chapter discusses the content and impact of the technological changes
that have been brought about in agriculture. Chapter seven traces
the impact of these policies on the viability of agriculture, on
cultivators and on agricultural labourers. Chapter eight deals with
the issues of food security and sovereignty. The penultimate chapter
talks of the farmers’ movements around the issues underlying the
present crisis. Agriculture plays a crucial role in our economy and
society. The last chapter tries to suggest the kinds of support that
this sector requires, and an alternative model of development for
the country, in which agriculture would get its due recognition and
priority.
In our work, we have received help, support and encouragement
from many individuals and organisations. First and foremost, our
gratitude goes to the people of Punjab and Vidarbha. We would
also like to thank the peasant leaders and activists of the two regions,
in particular Bharatiya Kisan Union (Ekta), Vidarbha Jan Andolan
Samiti (VJAS) and Vijay Jawandiya. Professor Amit Bhaduri,
Professor Sucha Singh Gill of Patiala University, Dr. Sukhpal Singh
of Punjab Agricultural University, Professor D.M. Diwakar of
DRISTI, Dr. T. Haque and Bhaskar Goswami helped with valuable
insights. Thanks are also due to those friends who suffered stoically
the demands made by us: cover designers, page setters, translators,
proof readers, those who were forced to read chapters endlessly
and give their feedback, and the tea makers. Needless to say, the
errors remain ours.
We hope our work communicates the gravity of the situation.
lc dkV nks
fcfLey ikS/kksa dks
csvkc] flldrs er NksM+ks
lc uksp yks
csdy Qwyksa dks
'kk[kksa is fcydrs er NksM+ks
;s% Q+Ly mehnksa dh gene
bl ckj Hkh x+kjr tk;sxh
lc esgur] lqcgksa 'kkeksa dh
vc ds Hkh vdkjr tk;sxh
Cut down
All these wilted plants
Don’t leave them thirsty and sobbing
Tear down
These restless blossoms
Don’t leave them weeping on the bough
This harvest of hopes my friend
Will go waste once again
All toil, of mornings and evenings
Will still again go in vain
Vidarbha
Debt, Despair and Death
The first thought that comes to mind when we hear the name
of Vidarbha is suicides. Something as morbid as people taking their
own lives due to despair and helplessness has translated into a
mere statistic now. When nightmares become a pleasant and
preferable preoccupation for an entire community, and death an
opportunity for a better life its time to jam the brakes and take a
check.
Eleven districts strong, Vidarbha region of eastern Maharashtra
is known for the cultivation of cotton, soybean and of late for its
alarming rate of farmer suicides. In fact six of these districts have
been declared as ‘suicide districts’ viz. Yavatmal, Amravati, Wardha,
Akola, Buldhana and Washim. Vidarbha lies just 700 km from the
thriving state capital Mumbai, also one of the centers of global
finance, yet the two are worlds apart.
According to the National Crime Records Bureau (NCRB),
suicides by farmers in Maharashtra crossed the 4000-mark in 2007
for the third time in four years. The exact number was 4,238, one-
fourth of the total number of farmer suicides in the country in that
year.1 This is after one-and-a-half years of farm relief packages of
around Rs. 5000 crores and a visit by the Prime Minister in mid-
2006. According to a study, the suicide mortality rate (the number
of suicide deaths per one lakh people) for male farmers in
Maharashtra trebled from 17 in 1995 to 53 in 2004 which is nearly
four times the national average. 2 In affected districts like Amravati,
the figure at times is ten times the national average. Since
September 2005, post-mortem centers in Maharashtra are open 24
hours by government order.
In Vidarbha alone, there has been a suicide every eight hours
in just three months (June-July to August- September) of 2008.
According to some reports, more than two hundred farmers of this
region committed suicide after the announcement of waiver of farm
loans by the central government. At the beginning of September
2008, nine farmers ended their lives in the midst of one of the biggest
festivals of this region, ‘Pola’. An increasing number of suicide notes
today directly address the Prime Minister or the Chief Minister,
2 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
THE REGION
The districts of Vidarbha region were part of the Maratha
kingdom uptil 1803 and came under direct British rule in 1853.
The Ryotwari system of land tenure adopted in the area vested
property rights in the hands of cultivators. Consequently, the better
Vidarbha: Debt, Despair and Death 3
for loans. Krishi kendras are the private suppliers of seeds, fertilisers
and other inputs, which are increasingly evolving as moneylenders.
This class of farmers (up to three acres), sometimes had to pay
rates of interest as high as 25 per cent. Farmers with land between
five and ten acres were not much better off. They also needed to
hire out labour at times i.e. work on other people’s farms. Often
they were forced to sell land or other assets in order to finance the
education of their sons or marriages of their daughters. Incidentally,
those with more than five acres of land will only get 25 per cent of
their loan waived as part of the revised loan waiver scheme
announced by the central government. The next category of farmers
with land holdings between ten and twenty five acres also needed
to supplement agricultural incomes routinely by activities such as
running a grocery shop unless they had relatives employed outside
agriculture who could send them money. For these farmers, the
average amount of loans taken every year was between Rs. 50,000
to 60,000. In this case, loans were taken largely from the cooperative
banks. Only those above twenty five acres of land could manage
with just returns from agriculture but the pressure of growing
economic squeeze and disenchantment with agriculture was evident
amongst them as well. Their average debt amounted to about Rs.
two lakh per year and was usually taken from scheduled commercial
banks. The loans are usually taken for production purposes. The
team met a large farmer (80 acres) who had to sell off nearly half
his land in order to buy a car and make a pucca building, thus
demonstrating the impossibility of incurring the same expenditures
from agricultural income. The impact of agrarian crisis is felt by all
classes of farmers, only the specificities vary.
Most of the farmers interviewed, talked of a steep increase in
the cost of cultivation and the uncertainty regarding the price their
crop would fetch. Almost everyone was dismissive of the loan waiver
as being a political gimmick and did not consider it a solution.
The details of different aspects of cultivation have been
presented towards the end of the chapter. The raw findings of our
survey are given in the appendix to the chapter.
Divine Intervention
We came across a tribal hamlet in Pandharkawada where no one had land in
their own names. Here annas (big brothers) from the Balaji Tirupati Trust
would come from adjacent state of Andhra Pradesh and give loans. For every
100 rupees given as loans, 150 would be taken back after six months. We
were later told that this money comes from the offerings to Lord Balaji!
received any payments even as late as 29 May 2008 (the loan waiver
was announced in March) and therefore they were in no position to
extend fresh loans to the farmers. This time is very critical as sowing
takes place towards the beginning of June.
All the above factors compound to ensure that majority of
farmers are dependent on informal sources of credit. The team came
across only one farmer who said that he did not need to take loans
from informal sources, but he was a large farmer owning more than
25 acres of land. Informal sources of credit also charge exorbitant
rates of interest sometimes as high as 25-100 per cent. Although
moneylending is illegal but it is still widely prevalent, with the
village postmaster, teachers, large farmers and input dealers all
dabbling in moneylending. In fact at present, input dealers are
increasingly taking on the role of moneylenders and supplying
inputs on credit. These loans often put a lot of social pressure on
the farmers and defaulting is associated with a strong sense of
shame.
CONCLUSION
Suicides by the farmers of Vidarbha are not individual acts of
desperation but part of a systemic problem located in a much larger
socio-economic-political context. It cannot be and should not be
reduced to a phenomenon confined to the individual self. In fact
18 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
the policies of the government are directly culpable for forcing more
and more people to this extreme step. They have driven an entire
community to a point of no return, a point where their livelihood
itself stands threatened.
Vidarbha: Debt, Despair and Death 19
Notes
1. P. Sainath, The Hindu, 12 December 2008
2. Study by K. Nagaraj of Madras Institute of Development Studies
3. B.B. Mohanty ‘We are like the living dead: Farmer Suicides in
Maharashtra, Western India’ Journal of Peasant Studies Volume 32,
No. 2, April 2005
4. Refer to the chapter ‘Science of Profits’ for discussion on genetically
modified seeds
5. Srijit Mishra ‘Risks, Farmers’ Suicides and Agrarian Crisis in India :
Is there a way out?’ An IGIDR Study
6. B.B. Mohanty 2005 op. cit.
7. P. Sainath, The Hindu, 27 August 2006
20 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Appendix
SURVEY FINDINGS
Farmers, Agricultural Labourers and Suicide Victims
1. Farmers who own 3-5 acres of land
Farmers who own 3-5 acres of land struggle to make their ends meet. Often,
they are not much better off than the landless labourers. Most of the farmers in
this category belonged to the lower castes. Some of them had received up to 3
acres of land during the land ceiling and land redistribution drive in 1975 but their
economic condition remains precarious in absence of any other support from the
state. Most of them have to work as agricultural labourers to ensure survival.
Some also collect tendu leaves to supplement their incomes. Some families lease
in land (generally of inferior quality) at the rate of Rs. 400 for 3 acres. Many
farmers said that they would not be sowing in the coming season as they were
not able to get credit from any sources. They were planning to rely on their work
as agricultural labourers. A strong desire was expressed to move out of agriculture
by the farmers of this category. Farmers with small and marginal landholdings
mainly use firewood from the forest as cooking fuel. They have to pay a bribe of
Rs. 500 to the forest guard for collecting the firewood. If they are caught by the
forest ranger, the bribe increases to Rs. 2000.
Farmers of this category have been using Bt cotton for the last 2-3 years.
The cost of cultivation of Bt cotton is Rs. 3000-7000 per acre. Farmers reported
that yield has increased by 2-3 quintals but their expenditures have also increased.
The problem of credit is severe for all classes of farmers, but especially so for the
people in this small farmer category. It was clear that they depend on moneylenders
for most part of their credit needs. If they do not repay the loan to the moneylender,
their land is mortgaged, animals and non-land assets taken away and sold. In
some cases, loans were taken from the moneylenders in order to pay back the
bank loans. Sometimes they would take loans from krishi kendras at
Pandharkawada town, but in this situation, they are forced to sell their crops to
them. Some farmers were of the opinion that, in the absence of institutional credit,
making moneylending illegal was in fact, going to leave them worse off.
According to the farmers, their cotton crop was sold at Rs. 1900-2000 per
quintal to the government and Rs. 2300 per quintal to the private traders. In the
absence of any storage facility for the produce, crop has to be sold immediately,
even at lower prices. Taking the produce to the market in Pandharkawada, requires
a further expenditure of Rs 1800. Most farmers rued over the low prices that they
received for cotton. For many of them, the price did not even cover the costs. The
22 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
farmers prefer not selling their produce to the Cotton Corporation of India, as CCI
offers them about Rs. 100 per quintal less than the private traders. Moreover,
there are middlemen who charge a commission of 5 per cent to sell the crop,
while the private agents charge a commission of 1.5 to 3 per cent for the same.
However, some farmers did reveal their preference to sell to CCI, as a bonus had
been given on some occasions in the past.
Some of the farmers were visited every 20 days or so by some agricultural
officers of the government who advised them to grow papayas and oranges.
Sometimes the small farmers were refused fertilisers by krishi kendras, because
of the fact that in case of shortages, they preferred selling larger volumes to the
larger farmers. This left the smaller farmers with no choice but to take assistance
of the big farmers for availing fertilisers, who demanded for unpaid labour in
return.
Consumption expenditure: The consumption expenditure of farmers in this
category ranged from about Rs. 50,000 to 60,000 per year. On many occasions
land was sold to pay off previous loans or to finance marriages of their daughters.
A farmer from Kosara village said, “Hum toh pehle se bhi kum khate hain (we
consume even lesser than what we used to earlier)”. In addition to this, state
support policies remain poorly implemented. For instance, job cards under NREGA
were provided almost a year back, but no work has been provided as yet. The
‘500 rupee’ relief package given by the Prime Minister for the ruined crop at the
time of laliya attack reached only a few farmers and that too after considerable
delay.
2. Farmers who own 5-10 acres of land
It is an indication of the growing unviability of agriculture in vidarbha that
farmers who own 5-10 acres of land are also forced to hire out their labour at
times. Some of them have to go to villages as far as 20 kilometers to search for
work. Women have to supplement their families’ income by collecting tendu leaves.
Despite this economic condition, farmers owning land above 5 acres were liable
to receive only partial loan waiver under the scheme of the central government in
2008-09. We saw in the villages that families have found myriad ways of self-
employment to sustain themselves such as tailoring, small grocery shops etc.
Farmers reported that their output has increased with the use of Bt cotton.
Some farmers said they would prefer to use hybrid seeds, but those were no
longer easily available in the market. The cultivation of Bt cotton has increased
the input costs of the farmers as they have to buy seeds every year. The cost of
cultivation of cotton is now Rs. 10,000 per acre. It is also perceived that the
Vidarbha: Debt, Despair and Death 23
shortage of labour has pushed up the wages of agricultural labour. The Madhyavarti
Cooperative Bank in Pandharkawada gave loans generally to the larger farmers
at an interest rate of 10 per cent per annum and a bribe has to be paid to avail of
these loans. A farmer also revealed that in practice, rates of interest were different
for rich and poor peasants as the latter had to pay a higher rate of interest. Some
farmers had taken loans from Self Help Groups (SHGs) at 24 per cent per annum.
However, they remained divided on its actual impact, with some farmers arguing
that the loans covered a very small proportion of the total input costs. Farmers
also felt that financial institutions favoured irrigated land over un-irrigated land as
collateral for giving agricultural loans. Private moneylenders gave loans at the
rate of 50 per cent per annum. In case of delay in the repayment of loans, assets
are taken away along with the crop yields.
During the sale of their produce, farmers get 97 per cent of the price at which
their cotton is sold. The remaining 3 per cent is kept by the private traders to
whom the cotton is sold. Government procurement is at a lower price than private
procurement. The payment made to the farmers is not immediate, it usually takes
one month. There are no storage facilities and therefore farmers have to sell the
cotton immediately after harvest (at the prevailing low prices).
Consumption expenditure: Consumption levels have worsened for this category
as well. “Earlier we used to eat wheat twice a day. We can no longer afford that,
so we have switched to jowar”, said one farmer of Bandhiwadhwa village. Some
farmers had sold their land or other assets to repay old loans, or to finance higher
education (computer and other vocational courses) for their sons, or to finance
their daughter’s marriage.
3. Farmers who own 10 to 25 acres of land
These farmers expressed a very strong desire to leave agriculture. They
wanted their sons to be employed outside agriculture and get jobs with regular
incomes in the town. Although irrigation is underdeveloped in general for the
entire area, some farmers in this category have private wells and tube wells. The
team came across the case of a farmer, who was in debt of Rs. 30,000 for boring
a well in his field. Unfortunately, he was unable to find water.
Most farmers of this category preferred to use Bt cotton over the hybrid
variety. Some of them gave the reason (amongst others), that higher yield added
to their social status in the village. Many of them had been using Bt for 5-6 years.
Initially, the larger farmers started using it and subsequently, the smaller farmers
followed. Farmers said that input costs had increased due to the use of Bt cotton
and buying seeds each year was a big problem. The prices of fertilisers and
24 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
pesticides increased each year by Rs. 50-100. Credit to farmers in this category
comes from the Madhyavarti Cooperative Bank or the moneylenders. A few farmers
complained that credit becomes most difficult to obtain, precisely when it is needed
the most (at the time of sowing and harvesting). Many SHGs exist in these villages
(between 10 to15 in most of them). Some farmers seemed to have a positive
view about its role and said that it is helpful in getting loans when they need it.
Farmers sell their produce to private traders, as the Federation (Maharashtra
State Cooperative Cotton Growers Marketing Federation) does not offer them a
reasonable price. In recent times, krishi kendras have also become buyers of the
produce. Since no storage facilities are available, farmers have to sell their produce
to avoid risking its spoilage, even if the prevailing price is very low. Two farmers
reported the case of crop failures some years back when they did not receive any
insurance money despite having paid the premium for crop insurance to the banks.
In the case of one farmer, the bank officials denied him insurance benefits on the
grounds that the crop insured was different from the crop cultivated.
Consumption expenditure: There were farmers in this category who had to
supplement their income by running a grocery shop or working as a carpenter in
the village. The income of farmers owning 20 to 25 acres of land was approximately
Rs. 1 lakh a year. Farmers said that they had witnessed considerable worsening
of their consumption pattern in the past 3-4 years. Medical expenses have
increased with heart diseases and cancer becoming more common place. Since
villages lack the required health infrastructure, significant expenses have to be
undertaken in taking the patient to Nagpur or to Mumbai and even Delhi for
treatment. The expenditure on marriages is quite high and is on a constant
increase. On an average, Rs.1-2 lakhs are spent on dowry for a girl’s wedding.
In the opinion of farmers of this category, the government should do the
following:
1. Provide irrigation facilities (that will increase the produce 3 to 4 times)
2. Increase the amount of credit given to farmers (by raising the credit limit of
institutional sources) so that they do not have to approach the moneylenders.
Credit should be made available at the appropriate time.
3. Schemes like NREGA and Loan Waiver should be properly implemented
4. CCI should procure the crop at a remunerative price and make payments
immediately.
4. Farmers who own above 25 acres of land
Vidarbha: Debt, Despair and Death 25
Farmers who owned more than 25 acres of land had private means of
irrigation. Water levels have fallen in the area as many of them have been using
bore wells for a long time. However, there is an absence of mechanisation (either
owned or hired) of cultivation, with only a few exceptions. Bt cotton is used because
it gives better yields than the hybrid varieties. Some farmers of this category
have completely shifted to cultivating soybean, because they were incurring losses
with Bt cotton. Some farmers have leased in land at Rs. 4000-5000 per acre. The
unavailability and high wages of agricultural labour was a problem cited by many
farmers who owned above 25 acres of land. The team met a large farmer from
Sonbatti village who expressed his helplessness and said that even he would
have to hang himself if the crop failed this year. The team also met a farmer from
village Deshmukh Khairgaon who owned two storage godowns. This farmer
reported that he had lost 150 quintals of his cotton crop to milli bug last year. The
main demand of farmers of this category was that the government should fix the
price of their output before the sowing season.
Cooperative banks, State Bank of Maharashtra and State Bank of India give
credit to farmers up to Rs. 10,000 – 15,000 per acre. Farmers of this category, in
general, denied that there was any requirement for loan from private
moneylenders. Some of them even denied the existence of moneylenders. It was
found out from other villagers that most of these big farmers act as moneylenders
for the rest of the village. The minimum debt on farmers of this category was Rs.
2 lakhs. SHGs could not meet the credit requirement of these farmers and hence
they were not very happy with them.
The selling price of cotton is around Rs. 2500 per quintal. Some farmers had
started the business of distributing cotton and soybean seeds to different villagers
in order to augment their profits. Farmers also had crop insurance. The premium
for crop insurance was paid from a part of the loan that they received from the
institutional sources.
Consumption expenditure: The total income from agriculture is around Rs. 5 lakh
per annum. This income is usually enough to cover consumption expenditures of
the families but not enough to meet the production expenditures. Many families
have members working in the towns who send remittances back home and the
family depends on that money to meet the consumption and production
expenditures.
5. Agricultural Labourers
It was observed that most of the people who worked as agricultural labourers
were either the landless, or those with marginal landholdings or the loan defaulters.
Most of them belonged to the Gond, Kolam (Scheduled Tribes) and dalit
26 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
collecting tendu leaves was another activity for subsistence. Some of them went
to Pandharkawada or nearby towns in search for work in the lean season. When
asked if they wished to migrate to a town, the agricultural labourers said that they
would not want to, for they had been staying in the same village for many years
now. The search for a better life was an impossible dream for them. Their
hopelessness had reached to such an extent that when they were asked what
alternative do they have in such a situation they said, “we have no other alternative
but to survive without complaining”.
6. Suicide victims
Out of the fifteen villages surveyed in the Pandharkawada tehsil of Yavatmal
district, farmer suicides had taken place in six of the villages. The option of suicide
and the inevitability of this option were omnipresent in the teams’ conversation
with the farmers.
In Kosara village, Eknath Kanauji Danande, a 56 year old farmer, committed
suicide on 3 May 2008. He had a debt of Rs. 13,000. He had been saving Rs.
3000 per year for 7 yrs in a SHG called Sanchayani. However, the NGO backing
the SHG closed suddenly and did not give his money back. Finding his hard
earned money embezzled and little hope of repaying his debt compelled this
farmer to end his life. Moreover, during the time of his death, his wife and daughter
were both ill, causing added expenditures which he was not in a position to incur.
In another case in the same village, Tukaram Paikaj Tonge had massive debts in
his name. He stopped eating, fell ill and died on 20 May 2008. However, his
death was not considered as a ‘suicide’ as per the definition of the term and
therefore his family did not receive any compensation. Suicide in this village did
not remain confined to the farmers, but their children as well. Madhukar committed
suicide as his desire to study further remained unfulfilled. This was an example of
how the agrarian crisis has impacted those dependent on agriculture in different
ways, attacking their livelihood as well as their psychology.
Indebtedness, impossibility of loan repayment and hopelessness were the
main reasons for suicides. In Yavra village, a farmer committed suicide as he was
finding it difficult to repay a loan of Rs. 50,000. His family received a compensation
of Rs. 1 lakh. They received only Rs. 30,000 as cash. The remaining Rs. 70,000
was put in a bank as a 6 year bond. Arjun Dhanraj Rathore’s father committed
suicide due to the same reason of indebtedness. He had become a defaulter and
the banks had stopped giving loans to him. His family members had not received
any compensation till the time of the team’s visit, despite sending repeated requests
to the government.
Some villagers argued that drunkenness, problems in the family and the
lack of desire to work, were the real reasons why men committed suicide, not
28 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
indebtedness. One farmer argued that the compensation amount received by the
suicide victims’ family could be the reason for a spurt in the number of suicides.
An observation cited by many of those interviewed was that reasons like
drunkenness were not the ‘cause’ of suicides but the ‘effect’ of the chief
predicament i.e., the debt that was haunting the lives of these farmers. It is the
impact of tremendous frustration and an extreme sense of helplessness that led
them to this miserable end.
Others farmers blamed the low price of cotton and indebtedness as the main
reasons for suicides. A Brahmin farmer owning 30 acres of land said he would
not hesitate to hang himself if the crop failed another year. Suresh Karla said that
increasing consumption expenditures because of social pressure worsened the
situation. He said, “If his (another farmer’s) daughter uses Fair and Lovely (cream)
then why not mine?” Marriage of daughters, a cause for worry and expenditures
in a majority of families in our society, has become a more difficult exercise for
the farmers of this region. Lack of funds for marriage, coupled with a bad crop
yield, has led many farmers to seek suicide as the last resort. Marriage costs in
this region range from Rs. 40,000 to Rs. 50,000. The dowry or hundi demanded
is worth Rs. 1-2 lakh.
Vidarbha: Debt, Despair and Death 29
QUESTIONNAIRE
IV Market
(a) Sale to CCI/state government or to private parties
Who do you prefer to sell to?
(b) Is scrapping of monopoly procurement good or bad?
30 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
V Consumption patterns
(a) Any food grains grown for self-consumption?
(b) Any changes in consumption? Why?
(c) Monthly Expenditure on food/health/education
(d) Does agricultural income cover consumption expenditure?
(e) Does agricultural income cover production expenditure?
VI Credit
(a) Need for credit
(b) How often?
(c) To meet consumption deficit or production expenditure?
(d) From whom?
(e) Any changes in institutional credit policy?
(f) Collateral/interest rate of institutions
(i) Moneylender/rate of interest
(j) Self Help Groups
(k) Are the agencies giving loans same as those selling seeds and inputs?
(l) Any switch from one agency to the other?
(m) Ability to pay back loans
(n) Loans as a per centage of agricultural incomes
(o) Pattern of recovery adopted by the agencies
(p) Agricultural credit societies or cooperatives?
(q) Will loan waiver help?
(r) Any distress sale of land?
(s) Amount of debt of a suicide victim’s family
VII Perceptions
(a) Corporate farming
(b) PM-relief package
(c) Crop insurance
(d) Why suicides?
(e) Would you want to continue with agriculture?
Vidarbha: Debt, Despair and Death 31
LAND REFORMS
At the time of Independence, India inherited a semi-feudal
structure with complicated tenancy arrangements (between
landowners and actual cultivators) over large parts of the country.
The ownership and control of land was concentrated in the hands
of relatively few landlords and intermediaries. The zamindars and
intermediaries’ principal interest was to extract maximum rent from
the land; they had no interest in increasing the productivity of land.
The actual tillers of the land also did not have any incentive to
invest or improve production techniques because they did not own
the land or its output.
There was a rationale for urgent and immediate land reforms
at the time of Independence – meaningful economic and social
equality could only be achieved with a more egalitarian distribution
of land and vesting ownership rights with the actual tillers of the
36 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
soil. Despite tall claims in various policies and plans, genuine land
reforms remained an unfulfilled dream for the Indian peasantry.
Land reforms involve three components – abolition of the
zamindari system, tenancy reforms and ceiling and redistribution
of surplus land. In all these respects, land reforms were seriously
lacking. Though the Parliament enacted legislations like zamindari
abolition and land ceiling acts, the enactment of these legislations
was merely an eyewash. Not only were the zamindars paid sizeable
compensation for their lands, they were also allowed to retain khas
land and more under the pretext of cultivating it themselves. The
land ceiling legislations, even after making liberal concessions, left
loopholes which allowed owners of large property to retain most of
their possessions. Before the enactment of the legislations, these
landowners were permitted sufficient time to divide their landed
property and hold it in their own, their relatives’ as well as under
fictitious names.
The land reform legislations were not intended by the reigning
political leaders to bring about any significant changes in the
ownership patterns. This was evident in the way land reform was
implemented. In a study, P.S. Appu has critically analysed the
implementation of land reforms in India since independence. By
1992 ownership rights had been conferred on some 11 million
tenants on 14.4 million acres of land which was not more than 4
per cent of the total operated area. As far as redistribution of land
is concerned, by 1992 only 2 million hectares of surplus land was
distributed to less than 5 million beneficiaries. In other words less
than 2 per cent of the operated area was redistributed. 7
The enormous inequality in land ownership in India has not
reduced in the last six decades. According to the National Sample
Survey (NSS), the top 5.2 per cent of the rural households today
own almost half (42.8 per cent) of the land, the top 9.5 per cent own
more than half (56.6 per cent) of the area, and the remaining 90.5
per cent of the households owned less than half i.e. 43.4 per cent of
the area. 8 Among the bottom 90.5 per cent, 41.6 per cent of the
rural households own no land except homestead land (the land on
which their houses are built). Another aspect of inequality arises
from the steady decrease in the common land and water resources
to which the rural poor do not have any legal rights but on which
they depend for fuel, grazing of animals and water for irrigation.
As a result of takeover of land for non-agricultural purposes by the
Backdrop to the Crisis 37
state and private interests (aided and abetted by the state, of course),
these resources have reduced considerably in the past decades.
AGRICULTURE AND THE FIVE YEAR PLANS
As far as economic policies are concerned, economic planning
in India began with setting up of the Planning Commission in March
1950. Till date a total of eleven five year plans and three annual
plans have been formulated. The country has entered the Eleventh
Five Year Plan (2007-2012).
Economic planning is not merely an economic exercise; it is a
political exercise as well. Society is not a homogeneous entity and
therefore it is meaningless to talk of universal goals which benefit
all classes, strata, sections and sectors equally.
In India, like in other developing countries, there was a
continuous rhetoric about changing the social structure. The
following Directive Principles of State Policy embodied in the Indian
Constitution were supposed to act as the basic terms of reference
for the Commission:
“(a) that the citizens, men and women equally, have the right to
an adequate means of livelihood;
(b) that the ownership and control of the material resources of
the community are so distributed as best to subserve the
common good; and
(c) that the operation of the economic system does not result in
the concentration of wealth and means of production to the
common detriment.”
From the very beginning, Indian plans have been heavily
dependent on loans, investment, technology and ‘experts’ from the
foreign countries. US ambassador to India in the fifties and sixties,
Chester Bowles, notes, “…Ford staff in India became closely
associated with the Planning Commission…”9 At the initiative of
the USA, the Aid India Consortium (renamed Indian Development
Forum in 1994)—a consortium of developed countries with the
World Bank—was set up in 1958 to provide the loans for Indian
plans. The policies regarding agriculture were shaped by the
interests of the developed world and in that sense were a
continuation of the colonial legacy. Even for food, India depended
on the US. As early as 1958, Prime Minister Jawaharlal Nehru and
the Planning Commission accepted the suggestion of the Ford
Foundation chief in India, Douglas Ensminger, that a group of
38 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Notes
1. P.Sainath, The Hindu, 12 December 2008
2. Economic Survey 2007-08, Government of India
3. Total area sown with crops and orchards, counting area sown more
than once in the same year only once.
4. This could also be partly due to acquisition of agricultural land for
non agricultural purposes such as special economic zones.
5. Area irrigated through any source once in a year.
6. Report of the Steering Committee as quoted in Aspects of India’s
Economy No. 46, Research Unit for Political Economy
7. as quoted in S.K. Ray “Land System and Its Reforms in India”,
Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Volume 61, Number 192,
January-June 1996.
8. NSS Report no. 491
9. Bowles, Ambassador’s Report, p 340 as quoted by Suniti Kumar
Ghosh ‘Development Planning in India: Lumpendevelopment and
Imperialism’, 2002
10. Mid Term Appraisal Highlights (1997-2002), Planning Commission,
www.planningcommission.nic.in
Chapter
Economic IIIReforms and their Impact
Policy 43
Irrigation
Even after sixty years of independence, three-fifths of the
agricultural land in our country remains dependent on the monsoons
and cultivation takes place under rain-fed conditions. This
dependence on the monsoons makes the Indian farmer even more
vulnerable. Commercialisation of agriculture has meant that crops
which require lots of water are being grown in the unirrigated
regions of the country, like Bt cotton cultivation in Vidarbha.
Only two-fifths of the agricultural land is irrigated, and there
are severe regional imbalances and disparities in access to irrigation
across large and small farmers. It is not surprising that the
technology of Green Revolution was introduced only in those areas
of the country where a well-developed system of irrigation already
existed. The existing system of irrigation can be broadly classified
into different types – surface water irrigation, groundwater
irrigation (tubewells, and wells, with or without pumpsets) and
harvesting of rainwater (through tanks and other traditional forms).
In 1999-2000, less than one-third of the total irrigated area (31.44
per cent) was irrigated through canal irrigation and almost sixty
per cent (58.76 per cent) was through private wells.
The state has to take the primary responsibility for building
the irrigation systems and reducing the dependence of farmers on
the monsoon. There has been an utter neglect of this sphere by the
state. The expenditure by all state governments on major and
medium irrigation (works) and flood control as a percentage of total
budgets of all states fell from 7.8 per cent in 1990-91 to 5.5 per cent
in 2001-02 (see Table 2 in appendix). The central government’s
expenditure on irrigation as a percentage of total expenditures has
also fallen sharply during the period of economic reforms. It fell
from 0.3 per cent in 1990-91 to 0.1 per cent in 2004-05. After
adjusting for inflation, the centre’s spending on irrigation and flood
control fell by 15 per cent.4
The investment that takes place in irrigation is also influenced
by political clout rather than actual requirements. The Marathwada
region in Maharashtra – the sugarcane belt as well as the
constituency of the present agricultural minister Sharad Pawar –
has cornered most of the irrigation benefits in the state whereas
the Vidarbha region in contrast, stands neglected.
Canal irrigation has suffered the most. The area irrigated by
canal irrigation decreased from 40 per cent of the total irrigated
46 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Subsidies
Subsidies to any sector are a form of support given to it by the
government. For example, if farmers are provided fertilisers at a
price lower than the cost of production of fertilisers, and the gap
between the two is met by the government, this would be the
fertiliser subsidy by the government. Agriculture is just one of the
sectors receiving subsidies from the government. Agricultural
subsidies take different forms, including food, fertilisers, petroleum
and power subsidies. The fertiliser, petroleum and power subsidies
reduce the cost of cultivation for the farmers, while the food subsidy
benefits both the farmers and the buyers of food. Subsidies for food,
fertilisers and petroleum account for about 38 per cent of total
government subsidies.8 In the period of economic reforms, there
has been a continuous attack on agricultural subsidies on the ground
that these are an unnecessary burden on the government’s budget.
Food subsidy: Food subsidies comprise of subsidies to farmers
through support prices and purchase operations of the Food
Corporation of India (FCI), consumer subsidies through the public
distribution system (PDS) and subsidies to FCI to cover all its costs.
Since June 1997, the Universal Public Distribution System has been
replaced by a Targeted PDS (or TPDS). The details regarding the
FCI are given in the section on marketing and price policies. PDS
is discussed in the chapter on food security.
Fertiliser subsidy: In the case of fertilisers, the Retention Price
Scheme (RPS) was introduced in 1979. According to this, the
retention price of fertilisers is determined by the government for
each fertiliser manufacturer on the basis of the input costs of the
plant producing the fertiliser. Each manufacturer is required to
sell the fertiliser to the farmer at a price fixed by the government.
The difference between the retention price and the retail price of
fertiliser is paid back to the manufacturer as a subsidy by the
government. The subsidy accruing to the farmer is on account of
the retail price being lower than the cost of production of the
fertiliser. Large part of the benefits of fertiliser subsidies is cornered
by the fertiliser manufacturers. Between 1981-82 and 2002-03, more
than one third of the subsidy (38 per cent) accrued to the fertiliser
industry and only the residual went to the farmers. The fertiliser
subsidy began to decline as a proportion of the GDP after 1989-90.
It fell from 0.93 per cent in 1989-90 to as low as 0.43 per cent in
2003-04. From 1994, the government decontrolled all fertilisers
Economic Policy Reforms and their Impact 49
larger proportion of the population. Last but not the least – the
large transfers and varieties of tax concessions given to the private
corporate sector. In 2007-08, concessions were given in the
corporation tax, excise duty and customs duty to the tune of Rs.
236,483 crores.
Even as the Indian government cuts its subsidies to agriculture
at the behest of international organisations like the World Bank,
IMF and WTO, the developed countries of the world continue to
give huge subsidies and direct cash transfers to their farmers and
agriculture. The total support given to agriculture in the OECD
countries12 increased by 9 per cent from 1986-88 to 1999-2001. In
the US alone, the increase in the same period was 39 per cent. For
Korea and Japan, the increase was 51 per cent and 11.36 per cent
respectively.13
In June 2008, police stations in Vidarbha were assigned an additional duty, the
distribution of fertilisers. “It’s not an easy job,” says inspector Devidas Chaudhary,
officer-in-charge of the Washim police station. Well known journalist P. Sainath
observes, “Rarely has fertiliser been distributed under such tight security, by men
in uniform.” Fertiliser shortages sparked unrest across rural Maharashtra. Apart
from fertilisers, seeds also seemed to be in short supply.
on this account has been rising. The rise may be higher than what
is shown by government statistics as these statistics do not factor
in bad quality or spurious seeds.
US multinational companies like Monsanto, through their
Indian subsidiaries, have been trying that the seed regulations laws
in India are changed in their favour. In 2007, cotton seeds were
surprisingly removed from the Essential Commodities Act, which
is the only weapon in the hands of the state governments to regulate
private seed trade and seed prices. As a result, the state
governments found it difficult to regulate the price of Bt cotton.
When some of the state governments reduced the price of Bt cotton
by promulgating ordinances, the US Department of Agriculture
referred to this and said “unwarranted interference by state
governments in seed pricing could act as a disincentive to introduce
new biotech traits/ events into India”.16
Irrigation Charges: The cost of irrigation depends on the source of
irrigation like surface water, wells, tube-wells, tanks or canal
irrigation. In Punjab, Haryana and Uttar Pradesh, the major source
of irrigation is water drawn from wells and tube-wells with
electricity and diesel pump sets. This kind of irrigation is much
more costly than flow irrigation i.e., canals, rivers and springs
(whose costs are practically insignificant). The average irrigation
charge in the five states for the cultivation of wheat was Rs. 298
per hectare in the 1980s, Rs. 832 in the 1990s and Rs. 1,725 in
2004-05.
It may be noted that while states like Punjab have been
subsidising water and electricity charges for irrigation, many other
states are being forced to raise the irrigation charges as they avail
credit under the Accelerated Irrigation Benefit Programme or Rural
Infrastructure Development Fund scheme, both initiated in the mid-
1990s.
Interest costs: The financial sector reforms of the 1990s have allowed
the banks to dilute the mandate of priority sector credit to
agriculture. Although banks are required to provide 18 per cent of
the net bank credit to agriculture even now, the definition of
agricultural credit has been modified to include loans extended to
business houses dealing in farm inputs, machinery, drip/sprinkler
irrigation systems, loans to the power sector to extend transmission
lines to rural areas, and credit to private companies and MNCs
engaged in construction and maintenance of cold storages, dairying,
Economic Policy Reforms and their Impact 55
Procurement Fiasco
The fiasco in wheat procurement in April-May 2006 is illustrative of the
government’s failure in this regard. The total public procurement of wheat was
9.2 million tonnes, only 13.3 per cent of the wheat output, a historic low. 19 This
was despite the fact that wheat production was higher than the previous year.
This failure of procurement was entirely predictable.
Private traders and the corporate sector had already started making direct
purchases from the farmers the previous year, affecting public procurement. The
pro-corporate changes introduced in the APMC Acts of different states further
displaced public procurement. The official minimum support price of wheat in
2006 was set just 1.6 per cent higher than the previous year, despite wholesale
prices rising 4.3 per cent in the previous year (and fuel prices rising at more than
twice that rate).20 Thus, the corporate sector was able to bid just slightly higher
than the MSP and buy up the grain. Speculators in grain were able to drive
market prices much above the MSP because of the previous year’s shortfall in
procurement and the low stocks with FCI (1.9 million tonnes on 1 April 2006). It
did not come as a surprise that farmers preferred to sell in the market rather than
to the government. Even though the government announced an incentive bonus
of Rs. 50 per quintal on 21 April 2006 to attract more wheat, it was too late as
many farmers with less holding power had already sold their output to the private
traders. Much of the grain was bought by private traders even before it reached
the market. Only 13.7 million tonnes of wheat reached the market in 2006, 2.3
million tonnes less than the previous year and 4.4 million tonnes less than the
year before that. 21 Sharad Pawar, Minister for Food and Agriculture, admitted
that “large purchases by private traders, including multinational corporations have
been a contributory factor for the low level of wheat procurement this year”.2 2
Perhaps for the first time since the creation of the FCI, private traders held far
more wheat than the government. The government was now much less able to
control open market prices and it urgently required food grains for PDS and its
welfare schemes.
Thus, a situation was deliberately created to import wheat from outside.
The government could have procured enough wheat in April-May 2006 by giving
remunerative MSPs to farmers, and preventing agri-businesses and private traders
from purchasing on such a large scale (as production was higher than last year).
But it did not do so, since then there would be no excuse for importing wheat.
Under-procurement was necessary to create the case for wheat imports. Wheat
was imported that year at prices higher than those offered to the farmers.
60 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
of wheat in the country. Often the imports are also of low quality
grain. On top of this, international grain traders are being given
repeated relaxations of the quality norms for wheat imports with
regard to pesticide levels, and the presence of pests, weeds and
diseases. An example of this is the very high levels of pesticide
found in the first shipment of Australian wheat in 2005. 23
With a steady scrapping of assured procurement by the
government, the farmer is now exposed to the fluctuations in
international prices where the rise in prices benefits the traders
and speculators and the fall in prices is passed on to the farmer.
Between 1997 and 2003, prices of many agricultural commodities
crashed in the international market which meant that the farmers
received very low prices for their crops. The private traders who
buy the crop from the farmer and then sell in the international
market naturally pass on the fall in prices to the farmers. The
absence of public storage facilities puts pressure on the farmers to
sell their produce immediately in the market. The market is a
buyer’s market or in other words, the sellers of the produce i.e., the
individual farmers do not have any say in the determination of the
prices. Not only is warehousing being privatised, multinational
grain firms are being allowed a free hand to purchase directly from
the farmers. Needless to say, this would only encourage speculation
and increase in profits of these firms.
In many areas of the country, the farmer is often not in a
position to take the produce to the market. Where loans have been
taken from the arhatiyas (commission agents) as in the case of
Punjab or seeds have been bought on credit from private traders,
the crop has to be taken to these agencies for repayment of loans.
The farmer may actually have no cash to take home at the end of
the long, arduous year!
be disastrous for the land and the soil. One of the gravest concerns
regarding corporate agriculture is growing corporate control over
agricultural land. This is one more way in which scarce and non-
renewable resources of the country are being transferred to
multinational corporations.
The Indo-US Knowledge Initiative on Agriculture, started in
2005, seeks to adapt the US system of contracts in Indian
agriculture. In the US, it is well known that as part of technology
and contract agreements with farmers, companies also enter into
marketing agreements which leave very little choice for the farmers
in terms of the inputs that they use, or prices for their output.26
Contract farming and corporate agriculture are not solutions
for the agrarian distress. If anything, they will worsen the crisis
and the farmers will be at the receiving end. The example of Mexico
comes to mind where the corporate sector monopolises corn, the
staple item of the Mexican diet. The consumers have to pay higher
prices than before and the farmers receive less than before. Mass
consumption has fallen and the corporations cater only to the elite
in the country.
The Indo-US Knowledge Initiative on Agriculture
2. CONTRACT F ARMING
The second board meeting of KIA explicitly talked about
“drawing on the US experience with contract farming”. The third
board meeting said, “training on growing crops under contractual
agreements will be conducted in both the US and India and will
include legal mechanisms of contracts and adapting the US system
to India’s conditions”. This would require farmers to switch to plant
varieties which are more suitable for processing and food retail
industry. The potential dangers of contract farming for Indian
agriculture have been discussed in this section. US-style contract
farming US-style will certainly mean doom for our farmers and
huge profits for the multinational corporations.
3. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS IN AGRICULTURE AND FOOD
The impact of KIA on intellectual property rights (IPR) in food
and agriculture is expected to be in two areas. Firstly, there is the
agenda of ‘harmonisation of regulatory regimes’. What this
essentially means is that the US IPR model is sought to be adopted
in India. In the US, even the publicly funded research in US
universities and institutes is patented and licensed out for
commercial development to companies such as Monsanto (Bayh-
Dole Act of 1980). Further, individual scientists from public sector
bodies can hold IPRs along with their private sector collaborators.
The Indian version of the Bayh-Dole Act has already entered the
Parliament as a bill. The sixth board meeting of KIA talks about
trainings in state agricultural universities in India about intellectual
property (IP) management and technology transfer issues, and for
the preparation to set up IP cells.
Second impact of KIA would be the ‘biopiracy’ of valuable
resource and knowledge in the name of collaborative research. The
Biological Diversity Act 2002 is meant for conserving biological
diversity, sustainable use of its components and fair and equitable
share of the benefits arising out of the use of biological resources
and knowledge. Under this Act, there are specific guidelines drawn
up for collaborative research projects like KIA. However, KIA has
been violating many of the notified guidelines of this Act. That
Indian law will be bypassed or violated in the efforts to import US
regulatory regimes is not surprising.
68 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
4. SEEDS REGULATION
The US agri-business corporations are trying to ensure that
legislative changes brought about in the Seed Bill 2004 are in favour
of private industry. The Indian face of Monsanto, Mahyco, has been
part of discussions relating to finalising the proposed seeds
regulation law. Although there is no explicit evidence that KIA is
being used to influence seeds regulation, the same can be expected
in future.
In two board meetings of the KIA, there were express points
made on how the private sector (read multinational corporations)
could provide more inputs for the regulatory process. The irony of
the private sector giving inputs for regulations, which are intended
to regulate the private sector in the first place, would have been
lost on our policymakers and government! The unfortunate truth
is that the KIA is trying to make knowledge in agriculture, like
knowledge is so many other spheres, a commodity produced by,
controlled by and used for the profits of the transnational
corporations. The Indian government’s complicity in such
‘initiatives’ reveals its own intentions and interests.
CONCLUSION
Whether it is declining public investment in agriculture, cut in
subsidies resulting in increased costs of cultivation, ineffective policy
of procurement of crops and finally the dismantling of institutions
like the FCI, all have worked towards starving the agricultural
sector. This sector is the lifeline of any society but is especially
important in our country as majority of our populace is dependent
on it for their livelihood. This kind of neglect and bias against the
agricultural sector reflects callousness towards the vast majority
of our people.
Notes
1. Agriculture’s contribution to Gross Domestic Product has been falling
and was 18.5 per cent in 2006-07. For an investment of 33 per cent or
one-third of its contribution to GDP, investment in agriculture would
need to be one-third of 18.5 i.e., at least 6 per cent.
2. Praveen Jha, ‘Some Aspects of well-being of India’s agricultural labour
in context of contemporary agrarian crisis’, 22 February 2007,
www.macroscan.org
3. Aspects of India’s Economy No. 43, R.U.P.E.
Economic Policy Reforms and their Impact 69
Appendix
Table 1 Table 2
Public Investment in Expenditures by all state
agriculture as government on major & medium
percentage of GDP irrigation and flood control
(at 1993-94 prices) (as a percentage of total budget
expenditures)
Period Percentage
Year Percentage
1980-84 4.08
1985-89 2.90 1990-91 7.80
1990-94 2.07 1991-92 7.40
1995-99 1.75
1992-93 7.60
2000-02 1.54
1993-94 7.70
Source: Ramesh Chand,
‘Domestic Policy Measures 1994-95 7.60
and Challenges in Indian
Agriculture’ in Reforming Indian 1995-96 7.73
Agriculture edited by Sankar
Kumar Bhaumik, Sage 1996-97 7.33
Publications 2008
1997-98 7.42
1998-99 6.90
1999-00 6.45
2000-01 5.89
2001-02 5.51
Source: Handbook of Statistics on state
government finances, RBI 2006 as
quoted in Praveen Jha 2007.
Economic Policy Reforms and their Impact 71
Table 3
Expenditure on Agriculture in various Five Year Plans
Plans % of agriculture Share of agriculture,
and allied irrigation and flood
sectors to total control as % of actual
plan outlay plan expenditure
First Plan (1951-56)* 14.9 37.0
Second Plan (1956-61)* 11.3 20.9
Third Plan (1961-66) 12.7 20.5
Annual Plans (1966-69)** 16.7 23.8
Fourth Plan (1969-74)** 14.7 23.3
Fifth Plan (1974-79) 12.3 22.1
Annual Plan (1979-80) 16.4 26.9
Sixth Plan (1980-85) 5.8 23.9
Seventh Plan (1985-90) 5.9 22.0
Annual Plan (1990-91) 5.8 —
Annual Plan (1991-92) 6.0 —
Eighth Plan (1992-97) 5.2 20.7
Ninth Plan (1997-2002) 4.9 19.8
Tenth Plan (2002-07) 5.2 16.5
Over the years credit, which in usual parlance had been seen
as an important requirement of industrial and business enterprise,
has become equally if not more critical in agriculture as well. With
increasing dependence on inputs which have to be purchased from
the market, credit requirements of the farmers have increased
simultaneously. The requirement of credit is met from two kinds of
sources – formal or institutional, and informal. Institutional sources
in our country have primarily been the Scheduled Commercial
Banks (including the Regional Rural Banks) and the cooperative
societies/banks. Informal sources on the other hand, comprise of
traditional moneylenders; and the new kind of moneylenders like
the input dealers or commission agents as in Punjab. In recent years,
microfinance institutions and self help groups have emerged as
other sources of credit, propagated by many as the “magic pill” to
alleviate rural poverty.
At an all-India level, source-wise distribution suggests that more
than half of the credit requirement (58 per cent) is met from the
formal sources [Government – 2.5 per cent, cooperatives – 19.6 per
cent and banks – 35.6 per cent]. More than one-fourth of the
outstanding debt is from the moneylenders and the rest from other
informal sources. Small and marginal farmers, who comprise 84
per cent of all farmer households, get three-fourths of their credit
requirements from moneylenders and informal sources.2 This of
course implies that the large farmers, landlords and the agri-
74 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Loan Waiver ?
The annual budget 2008-2009 announced by Finance Minister, P. Chidambaram,
is most famous for the Rs. 60,000 crore loan waiver. According to the original proposal
for the loan waiver scheme, it was the small and marginal farmers (those owning
less than 5 acres of land) who were eligible. However there were many protests
regarding the limited number of farmers that would benefit from this scheme. A few
changes were made and the Agricultural Debt Waiver and Debt Relief Scheme
2008, was approved by the Union Cabinet. It covers all direct agricultural loans by
banks to farmers disbursed between 31 March 1997 and 31 March 2007, which
were overdue as on 31 December 2007 and remained unpaid until 29 February
2008. The scheme was meant to be taken up by the banks by 30 June 2008.
The banks include Scheduled Commercial Banks, Regional Rural Banks, Co-
operative Credit Institutions and local area banks, while the loans cover crop loans
and investment credit for both agricultural and allied activities (dairy, poultry farming,
bee-keeping etc).
The scheme was expected to cost the exchequer a total of Rs. 71,680 crores
against Rs. 60,000 crores projected initially in the Budget. The beneficiary farmers
have, in turn, been clubbed under two broad categories of ‘marginal and small’ and
‘other’ farmers. The former have been identified as cultivating up to 2.5 acres
(marginal) or 5 acres (small) of land, whether as owners or tenants or sharecroppers
(and not solely as owners, going by the original Budget proposal).
The marginal and small farmers would be granted a complete waiver of the
eligible loan amounts due (together with the applicable interest). The other farmers,
however (cultivating as owner or tenant or share cropper above 5 acres) will be
entitled to a 25 per cent waiver. While the changes made to the originally proposed
scheme are an improvement, there are glaring problems in the formulation of the
scheme itself, not to mention the inadequacies in its implementation.
While the scheme does cover farmers with land over 5 acres, waiving off only
25 per cent of the loan is insufficient. In many regions with dry and un-irrigated lands,
78 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
productivity is low and hence the size of land holdings tends to be larger. In such
cases it is often farmers who hold up to 10 acres of land that
are in deep distress. Debt relief amounting to a mere 25 per cent is of no real
significance then. This is surprising since it was mainly the crisis in Vidarbha
that led to an outcry which resulted in the loan waiver. For instance, a farmer
owning 10 acres of land in Vidarbha will not qualify for the complete waiving of
his loans, which may be only Rs. 50,000, whereas a grape-growing farmer with
5 acres of irrigated land in Nasik can get his loan of even Rs. 2.5 lakhs waived
completely. In Vidarbha, a majority of the farmers who are facing the crisis, own
more than 5 acres of land.
The benefits of the loan waiver are highly skewed. More than 50 per cent
of the loans to be waived in Maharashtra will be of farmers of the prosperous
Marathwada region, a constituency of Sharad Pawar, the Union Minister for
Agriculture. The scheme also does not cover landless agricultural labourers
who are in distress as well. Since the scheme has no way of waiving the loans
taken from non-institutional sources, the loans taken from moneylenders will
not be affected by it. Farmers will have to repay the loans of moneylenders at
high rates of interest. As argued earlier in the chapter, the dependence on
moneylenders and input dealers is often higher than loans taken from banks
and cooperative societies.
than 25 per cent in 1991. The share of formal sector lending more
than doubled between 1971 and 1991.
and sections of the consumers, where it has the lowest risk of default
and highest profit earnings. This meant consciously starving the
agricultural sector, the lifeline of our economy and society. Credit
to agriculture would fetch lower returns than credit to sectors like
information technology, but this cannot be used as an argument to
deny credit to the agricultural sector because it is crucial for the
sustenance of the majority of our people. Profitability cannot be
the sole basis for allocating credit in an economy. Social priorities
must take precedence over the insatiable drive for profits.
The effect of credit policy reforms on rural credit and the credit
flow to agriculture were disastrous, to say the least. The impact of
reforms has been negative on the farm sector on various fronts.
There has been a major decline in terms of accessibility of small
and marginal farmers to credit. The banking sector has ignored
the increasing credit needs of farmers as a result of increased
commercialisation of agriculture and dependence on purchased
inputs. NABARD has been witnessing a decrease in funds supplied
to it by the government and the RBI. The shift of emphasis away
from rural credit institutions and the lack of sincere corrective
arrangements for problems affecting the financial health of
cooperatives and RRBs, has led to a failure in meeting the credit
demands of rural India. It is unambiguously clear that the state
consciously and deliberately made agriculture unviable through its
credit reform policies and precipitated the present agrarian crisis.
THE ATTACK ON RURAL CREDIT INSTITUTIONS
The recommendations of the Basel Committee of 1988 (known
as the Basel norms) were extended to all sectors (including
agriculture) by a RBI circular to commercial banks in 1992-93
without any consultation with NABARD. The strict implementation
of these instructions (which measure the risk value of assets and
loans given by banks) would have meant that agriculture would
not receive any credit from commercial banks at all. The RBI soon
realised its faux pas and partially mitigated the damages in a
clarificatory circular.3 But the policy of not lending to agriculture
(as it was perceived to be a high risk sector and banks had to reduce
lending to such sectors under the Basel norms) was continued by
commercial banks in practice. The RBI supported this practice by
hinting to the commercial banks that they could price agricultural
and other priority sector loans at higher levels. A 2004 circular of
the RBI said, “If a bank believes that loans to a certain sector are
80 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
TRENDS IN BANKING
Serious attempts have been made in recent years by the RBI to
dilute the norms of priority sector lending, in order to avoid lending
Tightening the Noose 81
and may even have him arrested; the treatment meted out to the
corporate defaulters, on the other hand, is entirely different. In
their case, the banks not only lengthen the schedule of repayments
but also make provision for the bad debts out of banks’ profits earned
elsewhere. In 2001-02, Rs. 40,000 crores of the total bad debts of
commercial banks was on account of large individual borrowers.
For the public sector banks as well, Rs. 22,866 crores of the defaults
was accounted for by almost 1800 accounts of very large borrowers
(deposits of over Rs.5 crores each). 15 Hence the argument of lending
to sectors and individuals with lower risks is not adhered to when
extending loans to large borrowers and for speculative activity.
WHO GETS AGRICULTURAL LOANS?
There has been a decline in the share of borrowing by credit
size less than Rs. 25,000 (i.e. the class of borrowers whose total
bank loan is Rs. 25,000 or less), from almost 50 per cent in 1985 to
merely 13.3 per cent in 2006, whereas the large borrowings have
seen a greater share over the years (see Table 4 in the appendix).
The borrowings of smaller credit size are usually by small and
marginal farmers. The constant decline in their share indicates a
bias towards larger farmers and agri-business corporations who
have been the major beneficiaries of whatever credit has been
extended to agriculture. Over the years, an increasingly large share
of agricultural credit is going to farm sizes of more than five acres.
Also, the average amount of loans outstanding per account has
grown much more rapidly in the case of farm sizes of more than
five acres and above as compared with the credit accounts of small
and marginal landholdings. Needless to say, those without land or
other assets as collateral, remain excluded from institutional credit.
Apart from the bias in favour of cultivators with larger land
holdings, in recent times, there has been a remarkable increase in
agricultural credit which has gone to the corporate sector engaged
in agricultural activity. This has been accomplished by changing
the very definitions of finance to agriculture.
Since 2000, agricultural credit has grown by 20.5 per cent per
annum but it would be a mistake to view this as a favourable
development in agriculture. The recipients of agricultural credit
have undergone a definite change. About one-third of the increase
in total credit supply to agriculture between 2000 and 2006 was in
indirect finance. The share of indirect finance in total agriculture
86 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
finance increased from 15.5 per cent in 1990 to 25.9 per cent in
2002 and 27.9 per cent in 2006. 16
One of the main reasons for this phenomenal growth is that
the definition of indirect finance has been broadened. Indirect
finance traditionally included finance to the institutions that
support agricultural production in rural areas e.g. loans to
agriculture input dealers, loans to electricity boards. The new
additions include finance for distribution of inputs for allied
activities in agriculture such as loans upto Rs. 40 lakhs for cattle
feed and poultry feed, loans upto Rs. 30 lakhs to rural dealers in
drip irrigation, sprinkler irrigation systems and agriculture
machinery, loans for agriculture clinics and agri-business centres,
loans to NBFCs (Non-Bank Financial Corporations), loans for
construction and running of storage facilities, loans to food
processing and agro-based processing units and loans to power
distribution companies.
There has been a sharp increase in the number of loans with a
credit limit of Rs.10 crores and more. Furthermore the share of
advances with a credit limit of Rs.25000 in total advances fell from
35.2 per cent in 2000 to 13.3 per cent in 2006. Hence it can be safely
concluded that most of the recent increase in credit flow to
agriculture, after the decline of the 1990s, is because of increase in
indirect finance.
Rise in large credit limits is consistent with the changes in
official policy of favouring growth of capital intensive and export
oriented production pattern in agriculture. The changes in the
definition of indirect finance are also a reflection of this trend. There
have also been changes made in the definition of direct finance.
Presently direct finance also includes loans to plantations such as
tea, coffee, rubber, spices and horticulture as well as loans given to
corporates for activities such as bee keeping, piggery, poultry fishery
and dairy. Between 2000 and 2006 there has been a major increase
in the share of direct advances with a credit limit of more than Rs.
1 crore. The share of direct advances with credit limits between
Rs.10 crores and Rs. 25 crores as well as above Rs. 25 crores doubled
between 2000 and 2006. Most of the increase in the credit has gone
towards financing large agri-business enterprises and large
cultivators as is evident from the fact that the share of the number
of loans outstanding to big cultivators under direct finance increased
phenomenally since late 1990s.
Tightening the Noose 87
inevitable feature of the growth process which can be corrected by simplistic measures
such as providing credit. This is an absolutely fallacious assumption,
especially in the context of the agrarian crisis. Cultivators require credit to
purchase inputs and most of the micro credit loans are given for self-employment
purposes. Thus micro credit does little to meet the credit requirements of the
farmers. In any case, as we shall see in the course of this book, the agrarian
crisis has deep roots in the present and past policies of the Indian state and
cannot be solved by “band-aid” solutions like microfinance.
Secondly, the reliance on self-employment as a way out of poverty ignores
the nature and causes of unemployment in our country. Self-employment can
never be an answer for a developing economy like India with a vast labour
force, especially when labour-displacing and growth-oriented policies of the
State and private capital continue to generate more unemployment. There is
no infrastructure or marketing support measures accompanying these self-
employment schemes which considerably reduce their chances of success.
Thirdly, the “cheap credit” being promised by microfinance schemes is not
really cheap. At 24 per cent per annum, the interest rates are lesser compared
only to the usurious moneylenders of the countryside. What is conveniently
forgotten is that it was the banking sector and credit policy reforms of the 1990s
which withdrew ‘Priority Sector Lending’ from the rural areas, and allowed the
moneylenders to return in the first place. The interest rates charged in Self
Help Groups are higher than the Priority Sector Lending Rates of the banks,
RRBs and Cooperative Societies, and even higher than the interest rates
charged for loans for personal consumption (of cars and homes) in the urban
areas.
The much hyped high loan recovery rates of the SHGs often have a dark
underbelly. They are based on informal coercive mechanisms and peer group
pressure. There have been many cases where women have been forced to
take loans from other sources in order to repay loans taken from SHGs and
save their izzat in the village.
It is alarming that commercial and cooperative banks have started
categorising loans to SHGs as part of their credit to the agricultural sector. In
Vidarbha, the Perspectives team found that one third of the total credit of SBI
Pandharkawada branch, Yavatmal district, to agriculture in 2007-08 was in the
form of loans to SHGs. It is doubtful what proportion of these loans would actually
go to agriculture and what proportion would be diverted for generating self-
employment.
Tightening the Noose 89
vocal recommendations for this came from Bill Gates? What is the reason that global
financial institutions like Citigroup, ING and VISA were the official sponsors of the
International Year of Microcredit in 2005? Is it mere philanthropy and honest intentions
of removing poverty that are driving commercial banks and institutions like the World
Bank to advocate micro credit? Or is micro credit a way for these global financial
interests to tap the large number of small savings of the poorest and the most vulnerable
in the most backward regions of the world?
FARMERS IN DEBT
The function of the commission agent does not end here. Once
the produce is harvested, the farmer has to sell the produce either
in the mandi (market) to private traders or have it procured by the
government. The arhatiya in the mandi acts as the agent for the
buyer (government or private) and accumulates this produce to be
sold in bulk. The produce also needs to be weighed, cleaned and
packed in gunny bags, which involves extra costs and labour; for
which the arhatiyas earn a commission from the farmer and the
government. In Punjab an extra 4 per cent is earned over and above
the Minimum Support Price of the produce from the government,
for the procurement and processing of the produce. This is despite
the fact that a part of the cost is borne by the farmer, and the
arhatiya only acts as an agent between the farmer and the buyer.
The farmers get paid after the agent has sold the produce in
the market, from which the initial loan amount and the costs of
cleaning and packaging are deducted, leaving at best a marginal
profit for the farmer. Therefore the farmer is compelled to again
take a loan for the next crop. This also ensures that farmer returns
to the same commission agent each year for credit and other inputs,
since there is always some outstanding debt that remains.
Traditional moneylenders, traders and large farmers who had
surplus capital from other enterprises (Rs.60 lakhs and above)
entered this field. People have invested upto 20 crores individually
as the returns are attractive. There are potential investors as well,
who loan their money through commission agents since they charge
high rates of interest.
Who’s championing the cause of moneylending? The Reserve
Bank of India! An Expert Technical Group formed by RBI has
suggested in a report dated July 2007 that rural usury should be
legitimized by suitable legislations. The moneylenders will now
become ‘accredited loan providers’. According to this proposal, banks
will provide funds to the moneylenders rather than the cultivators.
It won’t be surprising if these advances become part of the Priority
Sector Lending targets. The arguments given in the report glorify
an institution which has exploited the Indian peasantry since time
immemorial. Now, suddenly the moneylender is the hero of “market
reforms” who’s ‘friendly to the borrower’, ‘has an informal approach’,
can provide the loans ‘any time, any where, any amount’. The report
forgets to mention the recovery procedures and the usurious rates
charged.
94 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Notes
1. This chapter “borrows heavily from / is indebted to (!)” the article by
Mihir Shah, Rangu Rao, P.S. Vijay Shankar “Rural Credit in the 20th
Century: Overview of History and Perspectives”, Economic and
Political Weekly, 14 April 2007
2. Srijit Mishra ‘Agrarian Crisis in Post-Reform India’ Alternative
Economic Survey, 2006-07
3. P. Satish ‘Agricultural Credit in the post-reform Era’ Economic and
Political Weekly, 30 June 2007
4. Ibid.
5. “NABARD union seeks PM’s intervention to regain lost glory”,
Financial Express, 13 November 2007
6. Vasam Anand Kumar ‘Case for De-Amalgamation of Regional Rural
Banks’ Economic and Political Weekly, 18 October 2008
7. P. Satish 2007 op. cit.
8. C.P. Chandrashekhar and Parthapratim Pal ‘Financial Liberalisation
in India: an assessment of its nature and outcomes’ Economic and
Political Weekly, 18 March 2006
9. Ibid.
10. Prime Lending Rate refers to the rate of interest at which banks lend
to their credit-worthy or favoured customers.
11. Report of the Advisory Committee on Flow of Credit to Agriculture,
Reserve Bank of India, 18 May 2004
12. Indian Express, 17 July 2003
13. Chandrashekhar and Pal 2006 op. cit.
14. Table 4 and Table 5, Gagan Bihari Sahu and D. Rajashekhar “Banking
Sector Reform and Credit Flow to Indian Agriculture” Economic and
Political Weekly, 31 December 2005
96 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Appendix
Table 1
Growth of Rural Banking India, 1969-2006
Year Number of Bank Outstanding Credit Deposits
Offices Rural
Rural % of total Rural % of total Rural % of total
Rs. crores Rs. crores
1969 1443 17.6 115 3.3 306 6.3
1972 5274 36.0 257 4.6 540 6.5
Table 2
Relocation of RRBs’ Business
from Rural to Semi-Urban & Urban Areas
Location Number of Offices Distribution of Credit Outstanding (in %)
Source: RBI, Basic Statistical Returns, March 1996 and March 2003.
98 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Tightening the Noose 99
Chapter
100 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian CrisisVin India
provided could remain the same in the initial phase. After this, the
second step for all countries was to decide their own bound tariff
rates for different commodities. Bound tariff rates refer to the
maximum possible rates that can be applied on a commodity at any
time. The actual tariff rates (known as the applied tariff rates) have
to be lower than or at most, equal to the bound tariff rates. The
third step was tariff reduction – to reduce all the tariffs (including
bound tariff rates as well as tariffs resulting from the tariffication
process) that had now been decided. Developed countries had to
reduce their tariffs by an average of 36 per cent over six years (from
1995) and developing countries had to reduce their tariffs by an
average of 24 per cent over ten years. A minimum reduction of 15
per cent had to be made on all tariff rates.
PROBLEMS WITH TARIFFICATION AND TARIFF REDUCTIONS
There were several reasons why the bound tariff rates continued
to be high, especially in the case of developed countries, even after
the AoA rules on market access were implemented. There were
several ways in which developed countries continued to deny to
the developing countries access to their own markets, even while
adhering to the AoA.
Firstly, the choice of 1986-89 as the base year period for
tariffication was flawed. Since market prices of agricultural
commodities were very low during this period, the bound tariff rates
were calculated to be very high. This was because the formula for
calculating bound tariff rates (see appendix) is based on the
difference between domestic and world prices, which turned out to
be very high for the base year period. When the developed countries
reduced 36 per cent from these high bound tariff rates, the final
bound rates by 2000 still remained quite high.
Developed countries also undertook dirty tariffication i.e., they
intentionally overestimated the tariff rates by inflating the gap
between domestic and international prices. This happened because
every country was allowed to decide its domestic price levels for
itself. Dirty tariffication was done particularly for high-value
agricultural commodities and for commodities produced in the
temperate zones (like cereals, dairy, meat and sugar) in which
developed countries would have faced stiff competition from
developing countries. Tariffs were kept low for tropical products
which were not produced by the developed countries, and whose
imports they required from the developing world.
Freedom to Trade and Freedom to Plunder 109
2001, the net diversion of food grains area was over 8 million
hectares compared to 1991.
The diversion of land away from food crops along with the
decline in growth rates of food grain production lowered the
domestic food availability. The primary export thrust was at the
expense of declining nutritional levels for the mass of the population.
The per capita production of food grains for human consumption
declined by 4 kilograms from 1990 to 1999, while the per capita
availability of food declined by 14 kilograms in the same period
(the difference between foodgrain production and availability is on
account of imports, exports and stocks).
Impact on farmers
The period when most countries of the world began liberalising
their agricultural trade under WTO, coincided with a drastic decline
in world prices of agricultural products. There was a fall in the
prices of commercial crops grown in tropical regions (like tea, coffee,
rubber and cotton) as well as a fall in the prices of cereal food crops
grown both in tropical and temperate regions. Thus, the dollar prices
of wheat (Argentine and US RSW variety) fell by 46 per cent between
1995 and 2001. The price of maize in the same period fell by 50 per
cent. The price of palm oil fell by 88 per cent between 1995 and
1999, and the price of jute fell by 25 per cent in the same period.
For sugar and cotton, the decline in prices between 1995 and 2001,
was 30 per cent and 50 per cent respectively.11
Since agricultural trade was now liberalised and the farmers
of developing countries were no longer protected by tariff and non-
tariff barriers, the disastrous effects of the price decline was entirely
borne by them. As Utsa Patnaik put it, “By liberalising trade and
by opening up at this juncture, the depression in the global markets
is being imported into the Indian economy and into other liberalising
countries.”12
As a consequence of this price decline, the livelihood of food
grain producers in countries like India was affected due to the
imports of exceptionally low-priced foreign grain. In the case of
commercial crops, again, it was the developing country farmers who
mainly suffered because of the global depression in prices. The
situation was worse for the commercial crop farmers because they
had to take large loans for cultivation and engage in input-intensive
farming, at a time when the government was removing all forms of
support and institutional credit sources. Mostly dependent on
Freedom to Trade and Freedom to Plunder 113
1990s, till 1996-97, the farm prices of rice and non-food crops like
coconut, rubber and pepper were rising at a rate of above 10 per
cent a year. However, with trade liberalisation, the rise in price
was very low (for paddy and pepper) or negative (for cardamom
and coffee) during the period from 1997-98 to 2005-06. In general,
crops with high export intensity or facing import competition
experienced wider fluctuations in prices than the other crops.15
The opening up of the agricultural sector to international trade
made the farming community in Kerala vulnerable due to a surge
in imports, decline and high volatility in prices, as happened in the
case of many other developing economies. While the prices received
by farmers were either declining or rising at a lower rate, the prices
paid by them for inputs were increasing at a very high rate. This
affected the incomes of most farmers, and especially small and
marginal cultivators (who have lower yields and high costs of
cultivation). The indebtedness of farmers kept on rising and
eventually they were driven to suicide. More than 900 farmers
committed suicide from 2004 to February 2007. It should be noted
that farmer suicides occurred more in districts like Wayanad and
Idukki, which concentrated more on cultivation of export-oriented
commercial crops.16 This is the price that the farming community
of Kerala had to pay for India’s participation in the WTO regime.
Despite large-scale farmer suicides over the past ten years, the
Indian government has not learnt the basic lesson that international
agricultural markets are not level playing fields, they are extremely
volatile, and agricultural prices are prone to fluctuations. Opening
our economy to this volatility and removing all public support to
agriculture at the same time, has proved catastrophic for our
farmers. The need to protect our economy and farmers from the
vagaries of the international market is obvious. Yet our governments
carry on with the propaganda of ‘free trade’ and its imaginary
benefits to the economy and farmers.
Impact on agricultural trade
The liberalisation of agricultural trade under the aegis of WTO
was a part of the model of export-oriented agriculture that
policymakers adopted after 1991. Farmers were told to stop growing
food grains and grow export-oriented cash crops in order to increase
their incomes, as well as the foreign exchange earnings of the
country. The liberalisation of trade, it was believed, would provide
farmers with incentives to produce for the world market.
Freedom to Trade and Freedom to Plunder 115
depend heavily on cotton exports, have been hit the hardest by the
secular decline in prices. And this is despite the fact that costs of
production for one pound of cotton are three times higher in the US
than in Burkina Faso (Oxfam report of 2001)! 23
The situation is ironical – a less protected international
agricultural market, and the removal of subsidies by the developed
countries was supposed to improve cotton prices and therefore
improve the lot of poor farmers in poorer countries. However, the
logic and results of ‘free trade’ have turned out to be different in a
world politically, economically and militarily dominated by the US.
Thus, in the period of declining world prices, the developed
countries increased the subsidies and support to their farmers,
under the pressure of the farm lobbies. This encouraged the farmers
to produce even more, resulting in overproduction. This
overproduction by the developed country farmers is then sought to
be offloaded in the markets of the developing world. Therefore,
during this period, there was even more pressure on developing
countries to remove protective barriers and open up their markets.
As a specific example, US took India to the court of dispute
settlements at the WTO and forced it to remove all its quantitative
restrictions on imports in 2001.
CONCLUSION
It is abundantly clear by now that the rules of the game in
WTO negotiating rounds are heavily biased in favour of the
developed countries. It is also obvious that the developed countries
have always tried to, and will continue to try to, protect their own
markets, rich corporate farmers, and agri-business corporations
from the imports of developing countries like India. How much
countries like India can wrangle out of the WTO for themselves
depends on their bargaining prowess on the negotiating table. For
this, India and other developing countries have grouped themselves
into blocs and alliances (like the G-20 and G-33) to negotiate with
the OECD countries, US and the European Union.
However, these blocs are not stable as the interests of
constituent countries like Brazil, Russia and China differ with
respect to different commodities. For example, for a particular
commodity, one member of G-33 might be an importer and another
member might be an exporter. In that case, their interests would
be diametrically opposite at the negotiating table. The alliances
Freedom to Trade and Freedom to Plunder 119
are borne out of common economic interests, and they can be easily
broken or compromised if a country’s interests are better served
elsewhere (like, by directly negotiating with US or the EU).
Much of the gains from trade will also depend on who are
presently India’s political, economic and military (now nuclear?)
friends and who are the foes. Increased agricultural trade may come
at the cost of India having to give concessions on other spheres of
foreign or economic policy. The same is true for intra-WTO
negotiations as well. If the US and EU actually agree to larger cuts
on their farm subsidies, India and other developing countries will
have to agree to larger concessions in the areas of Non-Agricultural
Market Access (NAMA) and Trade Related Intellectual Property
Rights (TRIPS). There can be no benefit to India’s agricultural
exports, without our economy having to give concessions in some
other area related to trade, services, foreign investment and
intellectual property rights.
In return for dubious gains and promised benefits, India has
ended all possibilities of planned development of its domestic
agricultural sector by joining the Agreement on Agriculture. The
sector has now become so sensitive to the price fluctuations and
volatility of the international market that it has become impossible
to protect the livelihoods of our farmers or the food security needs
of our country. Rather, the liberalisation of agricultural trade has
thrown many more farmers into the clutches of despair and finally,
suicide.
While the alleged benefits of ‘free trade’ under the WTO regime
remain elusive, and are likely to remain unclear for a long while,
its high costs for our farmers and our economy is explicitly visible.
In such a scenario, the well-advertised bravado of our Minister for
Commerce and Industry at the different rounds of WTO Ministerial
Conferences and negotiations, matters little. The question that has
to be asked is whose interests our governments are actually serving
by continuing to be a part of the WTO and agreeing to this regime
of unequal and unfair trade agreements.
Notes
1. Bhaskar Goswami “Doha Round: Mercantilist not Developmental for
Agriculture”, 10 October 2008 , http://bhaskargoswami.wordpress.com/
2. Devinder Sharma “The Great Trade Robbery” September 2003,
www.indiatogether.org
120 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Appendix
Table 1
Total Aggregate Measure of Support (AMS) in Selected
Countries: Actual Estimated by WTO Secretariat
Country Value of AMS in Percentage share Value of AMS in
the Base Period of AMS in 1998
(1986-88) agricultural GDP (in US$ billion)
(in US$ billion) in 1986-88
European Union 116.54 79.97 114.61
Table 2
Total Support Estimate of Select OECD countries
(in million US$)
Country 1986-88 1999-2001 Percentage
change
Market Access
WTO sought to homogenise the rules for tariff and non-tariff barriers for all
the countries, differentiating only between developed and developing countries.
It recognised the needs of the latter to have a higher degree of protection of
domestic markets compared to the developed countries. Market access can be
divided into four elements – tariffs, bound and applied tariff rates, tariff quotas
and special safeguards.
1. Tariffs
According to the AoA, market access for agricultural products is to be
governed by a ‘tariffs only’ regime. The agreement states that there can be no
restrictions on farm trade except through tariffs. This meant that all the non-tariff
barriers (NTBs) had to be converted to tariffs by using a formula (i.e. the extent of
protection provided to a commodity remained the same, but the form of protection
had to be changed from NTBs to tariffs). This was known as the process of
tariffication. The formula for tarrification is given below.
Tariffication formula: Tariffication meant the conversion of the full extent of
protection given to a product through both tariffs and NTBs to an ordinary tariff
rate. The tariff equivalent was calculated as follows:
T = (Pd – Pw)/ P w X 100,
where T = ad valorem tariff equivalent
Pd = domestic price (e.g. wholesale price)
Pw = world reference price (import or export parity price)
Base year – the average of three years, 1986, 1987 and 1988
After this, the second step for all countries was to decide their own bound
tariff rates for different commodities. Bound tariff rates refer to the maximum
possible rates that can be applied on a commodity at any time. The actual tariff
rates (known as the applied tariff rates) have to be lower than or at most, equal to
the bound tariff rates.
The third step was tariff reduction – to reduce all the tariffs (including bound
tariff rates as well as tariffs resulting from the tariffication process) that had now
been decided. Developed countries had to reduce their tariffs by an average of
36 per cent over six years (from 1995) and developing countries had to reduce
their tariffs by an average of 24 per cent over ten years. A minimum reduction of
15 per cent had to be made on all tariff rates.
The fourth condition was that current market access had to be maintained
by all countries and minimum access opportunities had to be provided in cases
where they did not exist before. Current market access referred to the quantity of
Freedom to Trade and Freedom to Plunder 123
(both export subsidies and domestic support, which we will study later). The peace
clause meant that no country could question the subsidies given by the developed
countries (about which, we shall study below) for nine years.
The Special Safeguard (SSG) Provision of the AoA
The AoA states that for products whose NTBs have been converted to tariffs,
governments can impose additional tariffs if the volume of imports of that product
increases above a certain threshold, or if the price of imports of that product falls
below a trigger price. Both conditions indicate situations where imports could
flood the domestic market, and greatly harm the domestic producers. This provision
cannot be invoked for products which were protected only by tariffs before 1995,
or for products for which bound tariff rates were declared after 1995.
The agricultural SSG is the simplest of all WTO safeguards. The right to
make use of the SSG provision has been reserved by 36 developed countries
(for a limited number of products). Since majority of the developing countries
chose to declare bound tariff rates for their commodities instead of undertaking
tariffication, they do not have access to this provision.
Domestic Support
The main complaint against domestic support measures is that they
encourage over-production and are trade-distorting in nature. For example, if the
government buys wheat at a support price higher than the market price of wheat,
it acts as an incentive for more and more farmers in the country to grow wheat. It
is alleged that this overproduction increases supplies in world markets (by reducing
demand for imports or increasing the supply of exports) and depresses world
prices. Domestic support measures often undermine (nullify) commitments in the
areas of market access and export competition; this was another reason for
disciplining them.
A key objective of the Uruguay Round was to discipline and reduce domestic
support while at the same time leaving some scope for governments to design
domestic agriculture policies, to suit the state and needs of agriculture in individual
countries. Thus, all domestic support measures were divided into two categories
– those that could be exempted from reduction commitments, and those which
necessarily had to be reduced.
Exempt Measures
Support measures which are exempt from reduction commitments are
classified as Green Box measures, development measures, Blue Box measures,
and de-minimus exemptions.
Freedom to Trade and Freedom to Plunder 125
and are subject to reduction commitments. Amber Box subsidies are measured
in terms of “Total Aggregate Measure of Support” (Total AMS).
Total Aggregate Measure of Support is the sum of the annual values of
§ Product-specific AMS (the total level of support provided for each basic
agricultural product through price support, direct payment etc.)
§ Non-product-specific AMS (the total level of support provided by policies that
are directed at the agricultural sector as a whole for e.g. input subsidies)
§ Equivalent Measurement of Support (product-specific support for which it is
impractical to use the AMS methodology).
Total AMS is expressed as a percentage of the total value of output of
agriculture. It does not have to be reduced if it is less than 5 per cent in case of
the developed countries and 10 per cent in case of developing countries.
Otherwise, as per the AoA, developed countries have to reduce their AMS by 20
per cent in equal annual installments over the implementation period of six years
and the developing countries have to reduce it by 13.3 per cent over a period of
ten years.
The initial AMS calculations were to be based on the levels of support that
existed during 1986-88. Product-specific AMS (or market price support) was
calculated using the gap between the applied administrative price and the fixed
external reference (world) price.
Chapter VI Science of Profit 127
Science of Profit
Technological Changes in Agriculture
had ordered 600 tonnes of wheat seed from Mexico. In the fall of
1966, India spent $2.5 million for 18,000 tonnes of Mexican wheat
seed. By 1968, nearly half the wheat planted came from Borlaug’s
dwarf varieties. By 1972-73, 16.8 million hectares were planted with
dwarf wheat and 15.7 million hectares with dwarf rice across the
third world. Up to 94 per cent of the hybrid rice area was in Asia,
with half of it in India.
What did Green Revolution do?
Technically speaking, there were three basic elements in the
Green Revolution approach:
§ The quantitative expansion of area under cultivation, which was
being done since 1947, continued.
§ Double-cropping of existing farmland: Instead of one crop season
per year, the decision was made to have two. The one-season-
per-year practice was based on the fact that there is only one
natural monsoon per year; so the increase in demand for water
for the two cropping seasons needed to be met with. Dams were
built to arrest large volumes of monsoon water which was earlier
being wasted. Simple irrigation techniques were also adopted.
§ The most important aspect of Green Revolution was the use of
high yielding varieties (HYVs) of seeds. Initially these seeds were
used for wheat and rice cultivation, but later HYV millets and
corn were also developed. These HYVs were in reality high
responsive seeds, HRVs; this meant that high yields could only
be attained under intensive application of fertilisers and water.
The Green Revolution resulted in a record grain output of 131
million tonnes in 1978-79, establishing India as one of the world’s
biggest agricultural producers. India also became an exporter of
food grains around that time. Yield per unit of farmland improved
by more than 30 per cent between 1947 and 1979. The crop area
under HYV varieties grew from 7 per cent to 22 per cent of the total
cultivated area during the 10 years of the Green Revolution. More
than 70 per cent of the wheat crop area, 35 per cent of the rice crop
area and 20 per cent of the millet and corn crop area used the HYV
seeds. The document ‘Towards a New Green Revolution’ produced
in 1996 at the World Food summit claimed that the gains in
production were in fact as dramatic as anticipated and that over
the past 30 years the volume of agricultural production had doubled
with world agricultural trade having increased threefold. The same
134 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
The International Rice Research Institute (IRRI) was set up in 1960 by the
Ford and Rockefeller foundations, nine years after the establishment of a premier
Indian institute, the Central Rice Research Institute (CRRI) in Cuttack. CRRI
was working on rice research, based on indigenous knowledge and genetic
resources, a strategy clearly in conflict with the American controlled strategy of
the IRRI. The director of CRRI, Dr. R. H. Richharia was removed, under
international pressure, when he resisted handing over his collection of rice
germplasm to IRRI and asked for restraint in the hurried introduction of the
HYV varieties. Reluctant to compromise even a little on his principles, Richharia
went to the Orissa High Court, where for three years, he fought a legal battle
that ruined his family, disrupted the education of his children, and brought
tremendous strains on his wife’s health. The legal battle was successful, for in
1970 the Court ordered his reinstatement as director of the CRRI.
Meanwhile, the Madhya Pradesh government had appointed Dr Richharia
as an agricultural advisor, and he set about his disrupted work once again. By
1976, he had built up the infrastructure of a new rice research institute at Raipur
(then in Madhya Pradesh, now in Chhattisgarh) where he maintained over 19,000
varieties of rice in situ on a shoestring budget of Rs.20,000 per annum, with not
even a microscope in his office-cum-laboratory, situated in the neighbourhood
of cooperative rice mills. His assistants included two agricultural graduates and
six village level workers. Richharia had created, practically out of nothing, one
of the most extraordinary living gene banks in the world.
With regards to the IRRI hybrid rice variety introduced in Asia, all of
Richharia’s predictions had come true: the narrow genetic base created alarming
uniformity, causing vulnerability to diseases and pests, with crop losses ranging
from 30 to 100 per cent. Most of the released varieties were not suitable for
typical uplands and lowlands which together constitute about 75 per cent of the
total rice area of the country.
The IRRI counter-strategy involved breeding of varieties with genes
resistant to such pests, taken from traditional cultivators of rice. This gene
incorporation strategy made it imperative to collect vast germplasm resources,
most of which were to be found in India. The recruitment of Dr M.S. Swaminathan
would be instrumental in the task of collection.
IRRI looked towards Richharia’s 19,000 varieties at the Madhya Pradesh
Rice Research Institute (MPRRI) set up in Raipur. Richharia had uncovered a
fascinating world of traditional rice varieties, some of which produced between
8-9 tonnes per hectare (better than the IRRI varieties); he had also discovered
Science of Profit 137
the susceptible dwarfing gene of the IRRI varieties. His extension work among the
farmers would soon begin to pose a direct challenge to IRRI itself.
IRRI staff members journeyed to Raipur and asked for his material. He refused
because he had not studied the material himself. So IRRI did the next best thing: it got
the MPRRI to shut down.
The Indian Council for Agricultural Research (ICAR) floated a scheme for
agricultural development in Madhya Pradesh, particularly for rice. The World
Bank contributed Rs.4 crores. The condition laid down was: close down the
MPRRI, since it would lead to a ‘duplication of work.’ At a special meeting of the
MPRRI Board, Madhya Pradesh’s Chief Secretary was present, who was not a
trustee and was earlier connected with the Ford Foundation. A resolution was
passed closing down the Institute, and the rice germplasm passed over to the
Jawaharlal Nehru Krishi Vishwa Vidyalaya (JNKVV)s. Scientists were sent to
IRRI for training in germplasm transfer, and Richharia’s team was disbanded.
This time too, they locked Dr. Richharia’s rooms and took away all his research
papers.
It is also relevant to point out here that Dr. Richharia’s collection of 19,000
rice varieties is today in the hands of the Indira Gandhi Agricultural University
(IGAU), Raipur, which has since then added (only) another 5,000 varieties. The
official number of samples existing with IGAU is therefore 24,000. In 2002,
IGAU signed a MoU with Syngenta, for a collaborative “research” agreement
that would have entailed the transfer of this rice germplasm collection from the
University to the corporation’s laboratories. Syngenta was to have marketed
new rice varieties developed by it using this gene stock and paid royalties to
the University. A local newspaper “leaked” the story and the resultant outcry in
the local media forced the University to cancel the agreement.
Source: Vandana Shiva, The Violence of the Green Revolution
and technologies. The new hybrid wheat of the 1960s used three
times more water than the traditional varieties. There was a huge
increase in the number of wells to meet the growing needs. Many
wells were made possible only through the installation of tube wells.
The usage of water for irrigation fast exceeded the rate of recharge
of groundwater creating “black zones” in many parts where Green
Revolution was introduced. Water tables threatened to go down so
deep that soon lifting water to the surface would require very heavy
138 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
global revenue was $56 billion, generating net earnings of $814 million, making
it wealthier than many developing nations. Cargill controls about one-fourth of
the world’s grain production. This gives the company unparalleled power to
control prices around the world. It does this by either flooding the markets with
grain or by keeping its grain transportation ships at high seas for months. The
company’s control over the market goes to the extent of owning satellites, which
predict future drought prone or bountiful areas across the world. It is also the
second largest phosphate fertiliser producer in the world.
Monsanto, another US based company deals in genetically modified crops,
agro-chemicals, seeds and bovine growth hormones. The company operates
in 52 countries and is the largest seller of GM crops in the world. 80 per cent of
the world’s farmlands planted with GM crops in 1999 were Monsanto products.
It is the second largest seed company in the world with global sales of $ 1,700
million. A major chunk of Monsanto’s income comes from its Roundup Ready
(brand name for glyphosate- resistant crop) GM crops and Roundup herbicides.
Being the biggest seller of GM crops in the world, its major sales are in US,
Canada and Argentina and smaller sales in India and South Africa. Monsanto
has been unsuccessful in Europe as its campaign to commercialise GM crop
misfired evoking a moratorium.
DuPont’s acquisition of Pioneer Hi-Bred in 1999 has made it the largest
seed company in the world. Dupont recorded a turnover of $ 247 billion in
2001, agriculture accounting for 16 per cent of that. Dupont’s acquisition is a
step in its effort to shift in a direction of self-development of GE crops, resistant
to its herbicides and pesticides. Dupont’s share in the seed market will facilitate
the sale of these GM products directly to the farmers.
The top twenty corporations of the world are responsible for a quarter of
the world’s economic activity while employing less than one per cent of the
population. Three companies – Cargill, Archer Daniels Midlands and Bunge –
control nearly 90 per cent of global grain trade while DuPont and Monsanto
dominate the global seed market. Eleven firms account for about half the world
sales of seeds, of which about a quarter are sales of genetically engineered
seeds. Syngenta, Bayer, Monsanto, BASF, Dow and DuPont together control
85 per cent of the annual pesticide market valued at 30 billion US dollars.
Corporate takeover of agriculture has been achieved through a process of
‘vertical integration’ which means taking over of the entire food production cycle,
from the development of proprietary strains of crop species and the sale of
seeds to farmers right down to the distribution and retail sales of food products
in supermarkets.
142 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Claims of GM Technology
Likely future developments in Genetically Modified seeds technology includes:
q Continued development of herbicide-tolerant, virus- and pest-resistant crops.
q Methods to speed up traditional plant breeding.
q Further development of fruit and vegetables in which the production of ethylene is
suppressed so as to delay ripening.
q Modification of oils, fats and starches to improve processing or dietary
characteristics.
q Improvement of flavour, texture, bio-absorbability, nutritional content and
elimination of genes for toxic substances and allergens.
q Identification of genes controlling salt tolerance, resistance to drought, flood,
and extreme temperatures, and response to day length.
q GM crops that fix nitrogen with greater efficiency, thereby reducing the need
for fertilisers.
q GM plants that produce vaccines or therapeutic agents.
q GM bio-degradable plastics grown in plants such as rapeseed which could
begin to replace plastics from fossil fuels within a decade.
q GM plants for bio-remediation, i.e. removing toxic chemicals and agro-
chemical residues from the soil.
146 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
show that the yields have suffered. In India, excluding Gujarat, most
states have had fluctuating yields with Bt cotton. In the very first
year of commercial Bt Cotton cultivation in India (2002-03), the largest
survey on performance was done in Andhra Pradesh, by the
Department of Agriculture which covered 53 per cent of all Bt cotton
farmers in the state. In the survey 71 per cent farmers reported low
yields when compared to local hybrids. In 2004, the Andhra Pradesh
government officially ordered Monsanto Mahyco Biotechnology Limited
(MMBL) to pay compensation to the tune of Rs. 4 crores to Bt Cotton
farmers who lost their crop, which the company refused to do.
Though widespread scientific research has been going on for quite
some time to study possible uses of the GM technique such as those
mentioned above, there have been no large-scale successful field tests
as yet. The potential risks of GM crops are many. First, we cannot
know the exact content of these crops. It takes heavy finance to get
this analysis done in laboratories. Most of the developing countries do
not possess analytical techniques to compare GM with non-GM foods.
Most results that are reported to the public simply quote
laboratory results. Needless to say that the probability of these
crops failing to show promised results once planted in the natural
environment with less than perfect soil, water, and sunlight and
nutrient conditions is quite high. Official data and documentation
of test results is unavailable. Very few companies have participated
in public debate regarding GM crops and not many are in the process
of developing tools, which responsibly manage the potential risks
and uncertainties with GM crops.
GM technology also claims to solve nutrition problems. It was
for this reason that ‘golden rice (I)’ was released in India. It is a
strain of rice with an unusually high content of beta-carotene
(vitamin A), which was supposed to address the vitamin A deficiency,
common in India. This again is an overrated claim. India’s
experiment with golden rice (I) and Bt crops has been discussed in
detail later. For the nutritional benefits of GM crops such as golden
rice (I) to be actually realised, one would need to consume abnormal
quantities of the crop – this and the potential side effects are facts
that are very conveniently kept out of public discussions by TNCs.
It should be kept in mind that the technique of genetic engineering
is not natural and its harmful effects cannot be reversed. It is a
field of research where the scientific community needs to proceed
with extreme caution.
Science of Profit 147
Soon after its invention, Golden rice (I) was hailed as a saviour for the masses
dying of Vitamin A deficiency, especially the children in poverty-stricken African
nations. But the myth was soon busted and behind all the positive advertisement and
fanfare by the agribusiness houses, their true motives were exposed. Golden rice (I)
was found to be a failed weapon in the face of world hunger, a fact that the TNCs quite
conveniently hid from public eye. All it would do was increase the stronghold of these
TNCs on the developing nations, and promote US political domination. Once this
was understood and brought out in the open by researchers worldwide, the exuberance
surrounding Golden rice (I) died down.
According to the World Bank, global food prices have risen 83 per cent over the
past three years. The UN and World Bank have conducted a broad scientific
assessment of world agriculture, the International Assessment of Agricultural
Knowledge, Science and Technology for Development (IAASTD) in 2002. It concluded
that biotech crops have very little potential to alleviate poverty and hunger. This four-
year effort, which engaged some 400 experts from multiple disciplines, originally
included industry representatives. Just three months before the final report was
released, however, Monsanto, Syngenta and chemical giant BASF pulled out of the
process. This is merely a reiteration of the fact that genetically-modified crops
propagated by the TNCs are not the answer to the problem of world hunger.
The long-term impacts of GM crops are not yet known – not enough research
has been done to evaluate the environmental and health risks of transgenic crops.
Such knowledge is crucial before biotechnological innovations are implemented.
There is a clear need to further assess the severity, magnitude and scope of risks
associated with the massive field deployment of transgenic crops. Much of the
evaluation of risks must move beyond comparing GM crop fields and conventionally
managed systems to include alternative cropping systems featuring crop diversity
and low-external input approaches. Unquestioned expansion of this technology into
developing countries may not be wise or desirable.
Source: Vandana Shiva ‘The ‘Golden rice (I)’ Hoax: When Public Relations replaces
Science’ http://online.sfsu.edu/~rone/GEessays/goldenricehoax.html
154 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
CONCLUSION
In the context of discussing appropriate technology in agriculture,
the experiments with organic farming are worth mentioning. Organic
farming is a form of agriculture that relies on crop rotation, green
manure, compost and biological pest control to maintain soil
productivity and control pests, excluding or strictly limiting the use
of synthetic fertilisers and pesticides and genetically modified
organisms. The experiments with organic farming in India are on a
small scale, and mostly controlled by Non Government Organisations
(NGOs), which in turn are funded by the same transnational
corporations. The option of organic farming needs to be examined
closely, but with state initiatives and state support.
The technological fixes hitherto adopted in agriculture were
implemented to avoid the much-needed structural changes in the
countryside. One thing which can be said conclusively about both
the Green Revolution as well as genetically Modified crop technology
is that they firstly and foremostly, serve interests of developed
countries and the transnational corporations. In the case of Green
Revolution, the adverse impact on the environment, soil and water
resources have become evident now. It has exacerbated the
inequalities across different classes of farmers and different regions
and states. In the case of genetically modified crop technology, the
evidence remains inconclusive either way as yet. In such a scenario,
to give permission for the commercial application of this technology
(as has been done in the case of Bt cotton) is criminal and
tantamount to using human beings as guinea pigs. Its possible
benefits notwithstanding, it serves to increase the profits of those
transnational corporations who are looking to control food and
agricultural markets of the world. What is most dangerous is that
any negative impact of genetic modification is/ would be irreversible.
Hence, utmost caution is required in the adoption and propagation
of this technology.
The immediate need of the hour is to stop the ecological
devastation being caused by the mindless application of chemicals,
rejuvenate the degraded soil and preserve our land and water
resources. Soil mapping needs to be done for the entire country
and a judicious mix of organic and chemical fertilisers planned for
different regions of the country. The question of appropriate
technology cannot be divorced from the social priorities of a labour
surplus country like ours. Finally and most importantly, no
Science of Profit 155
Notes
1. John Augustus Voelcker, Report on the Improvement of Indian
Agriculture, Eyre and Spothswoode, London, 1893 as quoted in
Vandana Shiva, The Violence of the Green Revolution: Third World
Agriculture, ecology and politics, Third World Network, 1991.
2. George Rosen, Western Economists and Eastern Societies: Agents of
Change in South Asia, 1950-1970, The Johns Hopkins University
Press, April 1985
3. Suniti Kumar Ghosh, Imperialism’s tightening grip on Indian
Agriculture
4. Vandana Shiva 1991 op. cit.
5. Agriculture And Food Security: Background & Perspective, Devinder
Sharma, www.infochangeindia.org
6. PL 480: Public Law 480-Public Law 480 also known as Food for Peace
(and commonly abbreviated PL 480) is a funding avenue by which US
food can be used for overseas aid.
7. Felix Greene, The Enemy, Vintage Publishers, March 1971
8. Roger Burbach and Patricia Flynn, Agribusiness in the Americas,
Monthly Review Press, New York, 1980
9. Dr Donald B Easum, Global Business Access Ltd, May 1998: letter
seeking endorsement from African leaders
10. Selling Suicide: farming, false promises and genetic engineering in
developing countries. Christian Aid, http://www.saynotogmos.org/
global_south2.htm
156 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Appendix
Letter by ‘Doctors for Food & Bio- Safety’ to the Union Health Minister
4 December 2008
Dr Anbumani Ramadoss,
Hon’ble Minister for Health & Family Welfare,
Government of India,
Nirman Bhavan, New Delhi.
Dear Dr Anbumani Ramadoss,
Sub: Stopping GM foods from entering into India
We, a group of doctors working as “Doctors for Food & Bio-Safety”,
approach you for your urgent intervention with regard to serious concerns
related to the impending deluge of GM foods into India.
Bt Brinjal is a first-of-its-kind food, with the Bt gene inside it, allowed
nowhere else in the world and reports indicate that we are just a few months
away from Bt Brinjal coming onto our plates, if the biotech industry has its way.
You are also aware of the fact that some illegal GM foods in the form of
imported products have already been discovered on Indian supermarket
shelves.
We seek your intervention in the matter on the following grounds:
1. GM crops are a product of an imprecise technology which changes
the genetic structure of the plant irreversibly by adding or deleting a gene
or a string of genes, usually from a completely unrelated organism. The
technology is imprecise and induces instability at the genomic level,
resulting in many changes at the cellular, organ, organism and eco-system
levels. It is for this reason that the regulation of genetic engineering has to
have a precautionary approach, since each genetically engineered
organism is a biohazard and has the capacity to multiply uncontrollably
and irreversibly. The implications of the deployment of this technology in
our food and farming are very different from its contained use elsewhere.
2. GM crops have been proven to be unsafe – they should not be
permitted without any long term and inter-generational tests. Today, the
regulation prescribes at the most a 90-day feeding test on rats and goats.
Even this is sought to be changed through the recently-issued ICMR
guidelines which have been drafted based on the principle of substantial
equivalence, which has been shown for its shortcomings again and again.
This is inadequate to assess the full impact of a GM crop as food. Long
term tests have always showed the adverse effects of GM foods. In 2005,
Science of Profit 157
domain but no review has been called for. Even the health ministry, which
has a mandate of assessing foods from food safety perspective, did not
undertake any biosafety tests on Bt Brinjal nor has asked for independent
analysis of the biosafety data of the crop developer.
5. Bt Cotton’s emerging health effects from the ground to be
investigated: Even though cotton was brought in by terming it a non-food
crop, the past few years of cultivation of Bt Cotton have brought to the fore
many health-related problems. It is now officially acknowledged by the
Animal Husbandry Department of Andhra Pradesh that there have been
animal deaths and illnesses after open, uncontrolled grazing on Bt Cotton
fields; further, the department has also written to the GEAC about the
shortcomings in the biosafety assessment of Bt Cotton and requested for
comprehensive biosafety tests which were not undertaken to this day. The
department has also put out an advisory to farmers not to graze their
animals on Bt Cotton. Further, human allergies are being reported from
different parts of the country when agricultural workers go into Bt Cotton
fields to harvest cotton. These reports have not been acknowledged by the
Health Ministry nor have scientific investigations been commissioned.
6. Consumers’ and farmers’ right to be GM-Free to be upheld:
Consumers have a basic right to choose their food based on their ethical,
cultural, health and moral choices and on informed choices. Farmers on
the other hand must be given a choice to choose non GM seed based on
their markets as well as moral and ethical choices. Present regulation in
India does not uphold consumers’ and farmers’ rights over remaining non-
GM. This amounts to denying a right of a consumer and farmer. In the
current context, entry of GM foods will also violate the consumers’ right to
know what they are eating.
7. No genetic engineering should be permitted on medicinal plants:
Recent media reports have revealed that four medicinal herbs - Jivanti
Holostemma adakodien; Brahmi Bacopa monniera; Ashwagandha
Withania somnifera and Creat, kariyat or Indian chinacea Andrographis
paniculata are being genetically engineered by institutes in Kerala after
acquiring the consent of Review Committee of Genetic Manipulation
(RCGM) under the Ministry of Science and Technology. This must be
immediately stopped and health ministry under AYUSH must release a list
of medicinal herbs that are never to be genetically engineered. Medicinal
plants identified under the National Medicinal Plants Board must be
declared as cultural and medicinal heritage of India. No genetic
engineering should be permitted on them.
Science of Profit 159
Further, the implications for ayurveda (which uses plants of the Solanum
species) of the release of a crop like Bt Brinjal have not been assessed.
This once again reflects the inadequacies and serious shortcomings of the
current impact assessment regime with regard to GM crops/foods in India.
8. Health concerns not addressed in the regulatory bodies: Through Right
to Information, information has been obtained about the representatives
who have attended various meetings of the Genetic Engineering Approval
Committee (GEAC), the apex regulatory body in India, which has been
scored as the regulatory body for decision-making by the Supreme Court.
We have information that the health ministry representatives have not
attended GEAC meetings regularly; one of them has not attended any
meetings in 16 meetings in a row! Health concerns therefore have not
been addressed in decision-making.
WHAT SHOULD THE HEALTH MINISTRY DO?
Befitting the stand of Pattali Makkal Katchi (PMK) as the first political party
in India to have recognised and understood the adverse implications of GM
crops/foods on India’s health and environment, the Ministry of Health and
Family Welfare should immediately announce its recommendations against GM
crops/foods and get the regulatory bodies in India to adopt a precautionary
approach.
The Health Ministry should highlight the known risks from all published
evidence so far and announce that the Ministry is in favour of a precautionary
approach and for a moratorium, as is being recommended by Dr Pushpa
Bhargava.
We urge you to instruct your officials to reflect this stand in their regulatory
roles and that the Ministry should write to the GEAC, FSSA, RCGM and other
ministries concerned in this regard. The grounds mentioned above should be
used by the Health Ministry to ensure that no GM foods are allowed into India
and by doing so, protect the health of all Indians.
Sincerely
Dr G P I Singh, Convenor, Environmental Health Action Group
Dr. Mira Shiva Director, Initiative for Health, Equity & Society
Dr R N Dutta, President, Orissa Homeopathic Druggists Association
Dr. G.S. Kabra, Environmental Epidemiologist/Lawyer
Dr Sivaraman, Member, National Siddha Pharmacopeia Committee
Dr V G Udayakumar, President, Ayurvedic Medical Association of India
160 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
– Sahir Ludhianvi
Chapter
Harvesting Despair: VII is becoming Unviable 161
Agriculture
Harvesting Despair
Agriculture is becoming Unviable
the economy. After all these problems, the farmer still has to face
many uncertainties at the end of the year – the crop may fail due to
pests or bad weather, the price that he would get for the crop is
uncertain, even when the price crashes in the market he has no
option but to sell at the depressed prices and he is not even sure
whether the year’s work will cover his costs of cultivation, leave
alone bring in a surplus.
The harvest, rather than signaling prosperity, brings with it
accumulated debt and despair. The farmer is left with unfulfilled
aspirations and also the realisation that they may never be fulfilled;
a realisation that he may never be able to send his children outside
in some other profession, that his profession has lost its dignity,
and that his relatives and peers outside agriculture have a living
standard which he cannot match. It is ironic that those who feed
the rest of the country have insufficient means to properly feed,
clothe and educate their families. Only as an exception and that
too with great difficulty, do children of farmers manage to move
out of agriculture. There are also no opportunities to acquire
requisite skills to move outside agriculture as the state does not
provide them the education or skills which would enable them to
get employment outside agriculture. The withdrawal of the state
from its responsibilities in the social sector and the privatisation of
even basic education and health have turned these basic amenities
into privileges rather than rights.
In a period when the economic growth rate has touched dizzying
heights, a significant section of the population has been left behind
in the process. This growth has been accompanied by unbridled
consumerism but has largely restricted itself to the sector of the
urban rich and middle classes. The growing prosperity of urban
India has generated aspirations amongst farmers in the rural areas,
which are entirely understandable. For example a large farmer
compares himself with the urban middle-class and realises that he
is unable to purchase the same assets with his income, while a
smaller farmer might look at his relative working as a clerk in a
small town and find that his children can’t get the same kind of
education and opportunities. There is no reason why farmers should
practice austerity while the urban areas ride high on a cocktail of
corporate salaries, Sixth Pay Commission, media glitz and luxury
imports. While we do not subscribe to this economic growth based
on wasteful consumption expenditures and personal debt, it is
ridiculous to take the moral high ground and blame farmers for the
Harvesting Despair: Agriculture is becoming Unviable 163
crisis and for “consuming too much and beyond their means”. If we
look at the actual consumption expenditures of farmers, i.e. their
spending on food, clothes, education, health, or marriages, these
are extremely low, but they still remain higher than their incomes.
The table given below shows that farmers owning up to 10 acres
of land (4 hectares) have a monthly consumption expenditure
exceeding their monthly incomes. It should also be noted that these
consumption expenditures by themselves are not very high and
are for the entire family. These incomes are average incomes of
households from all sources including net receipts from cultivation,
wages, farming of animals and non-farm business. The average also
hides the variations within a certain land-class and also amongst
regions and states.
not have the skills or education which would make them employable
in other sectors of the economy. Secondly, the pattern of
industrialisation being followed in the country today is labour-
displacing or capital-intensive in its character. This kind of
industrialisation is incapable of absorbing the large numbers of
people who are presently employed in agriculture. It should be noted
here that 92 per cent of India’s workforce is a part of the ‘informal’
sector, so called because of the uncertain nature of employment,
low and irregular wages, and absence of any labour rights for the
workers.
The fault in the present situation does not lie with the farmers,
it unarguably lies with the state’s policies and its continuous neglect
of agriculture, which is making it an increasingly unviable activity.
DISTRESS OF AGRICULTURAL LABOURERS
Village community is not a homogeneous entity. It is divided
on both caste and class lines. Apart from the cultivators of land,
the ongoing agrarian crisis has impacted another section of rural
population namely the section of agricultural labourers who are
either owners of very small pieces of land or are completely landless.
Agricultural labourers constitute around one third of total persons
engaged in agricultural activity.
This is the class which has always suffered the worst forms of
class exploitation and caste oppression. They are predominantly
from the socially marginalised groups – the Scheduled Castes (SCs),
Scheduled Tribes (STs) and Other Backward Castes (OBCs). Even
physically, the dalits and the tribals live in marginalised clusters
or tolas on the fringes of the villages and have a limited social contact
with rest of the village. The relationship that exists is that of
employer-labourer or that of master-bonded labourer or creditor-
debtor in cases where the big farmers also emerge as the only source
of credit (i.e. moneylenders). This antagonistic power relationship
also explains the socio-economic backwardness of the agricultural
labourers. Despite toiling the hardest, their condition is probably
the worst and they have always suffered abject poverty. Many a
time even small or marginal farmers or their family members work
as agricultural labourers on others’ fields their subsistence. At an
all–India level, for holdings less than one-fourth of an acre, wages
constitute the main source of income. Of late, many are turning to
some kind of self-employment or are migrating to the towns in
absence of agricultural work.
Harvesting Despair: Agriculture is becoming Unviable 167
Notes
1. G.S. Bhalla, ‘Income, Consumption and Expenditure of Farmers’,
Reforming Indian Agriculture by Sankar Kumar Bhaumik (ed), Sage
India Publications Pvt. Limited, 2008
2. NSS Report no. 508 as quoted in Aspects of India’s Economy, No. 46
(RUPE).
3. Report No. 508, Level and Pattern of Consumption Expenditure 2004-
05, NSS 61st Round, National Sample Survey Organisation.
4. Praveen Jha, ‘Some Aspects of well–being of India’s agricultural
labourer in context of contemporary agrarian crisis’ 22 February 2007,
www.macroscan.org
5. M Raghavan ‘Changing Pattern of Input Use and Cost of Cultivation’,
Economic and Political Weekly 28 June 2008
6. Praveen Jha 2007 op. cit.
7. See Chapter VIII on Food Security
Chapter
170 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian VIII
Crisis in India
INTRODUCTION
In the five months from May to September 2008, at least 80
infants suffering from severe malnutrition succumbed to different
diseases in two districts of Satna and Khandwa in Madhya Pradesh.
This is only the most recent statistics of recorded malnutrition-
related deaths in our country. From April to July 2005, 2,675
children died of malnutrition in five tribal-dominated districts –
Thane, Nandurbar, Nashik, Amravati and Gadchiroli – in
Maharashtra. 1 Maharashtra is one of the more prosperous states
of India, whose state capital is the financial centre of the country.
The list goes on and on, endlessly repeating the tragedy of starvation
amidst wasteful abundance in our country. Can the state still claim
that we are a food secure nation?
The issue of food security is somewhat independent of the
agrarian crisis discussed in this book. However there are two
important linkages. Firstly, the same policies which have brought
about the agrarian crisis are responsible for accentuating the food
crisis facing the economy. Secondly, food is the most important
Of Hunger and Greed 171
The reasons for this stagnation are not far to seek. The state,
in the period of economic liberalisation and globalisation, has been
steadily discouraging farmers to stop growing food grains and switch
to export-oriented cultivation of high-value crops. This has been
done through explicit announcements of the kind mentioned above,
in different policy documents (such as Economic Surveys) and
through price signals and procurement policy.
Eight million hectares of land under food grains cultivation has
been shifted to exportable crops between 1991 and 2001.10 The
policies of state which have encouraged cultivation of commercial
crops for export have come at a time when majority of the people
are suffering from chronic hunger and malnutrition.
International production
The reduced emphasis on food grains production is based on
the premise that we can import food grains to fulfill domestic
requirements in times of need. However, the international supply
of food grains is seriously threatened by a new menace – the growing
demand for biofuels. The US and European Union have diverted a
major part of their production of food crops towards producing
ethanol and biodiesel, a factor which is held responsible for the
recent inflation in food prices across the world.
The US, which was not a major producer of biofuels until a few
years ago, has overtaken Brazil as the topmost producer of ethanol
in the world with a share of 39 per cent of total world ethanol output.
Further, EU has become the largest producer of biodiesel in the
world with a share of 66 per cent of world biodiesel output.11 As a
result, there has been a phenomenal increase in the usage of corn,
soybean, rapeseed-mustard and even wheat, barley and palm oil
for making biofuels. The US now uses a quarter of its total corn
output to produce ethanol.12 If we consider the fact that US has a
share of 43 per cent in the world’s corn output, it is evident that a
large proportion of total corn production in the world has already
been diverted for producing biofuels.13 The US government is giving
large subsidies to its farmers to grow corn for producing ethanol. If
the US and EU have to meet their domestic targets for biofuel
production, the diversion of cereals to produce biofuels would
increase even more.
The pattern of global demand for cereals for different uses shows
the grim reality. From 2006-07 to 2008-09, the demand of cereals
for food and animal feed purposes grew at only 1.5 per cent and 0.2
174 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
per cent respectively, while the demand for industrial use grew at
more than 8 per cent.14 Clearly, this shift towards biofuels is and
will remain one of the major factors threatening global, and
consequentially, Indian food security. It is ironical that the ‘hunger’
for fuel to run cars and industries has gained precedence over
human hunger and under nutrition in the priorities of global
capitalism.
DISTRIBUTION: PDS AND THE TRAGEDY OF WHEAT
IMPORTS AND EXPORTS
Winding down the Public Distribution System
The procurement (from farmers), storage, transportation and
management of food grains are mainly the responsibility of the Food
Corporation of India (FCI). Food grains are distributed to the food-
insecure households all over the country at subsidised rates through
fair price shops of the Public Distribution System (PDS). Let us see
the changes brought about in this system of distribution during
the period of economic reforms.
The PDS, despite all its lacunae (uneven performance across
states, corruption and bad administration leading to leakages),
performed several useful functions. For example, it succeeded in
transferring grains from regions of surplus production (like Punjab
and Haryana) to regions of deficit food grains production (like
Kerala, Karnataka and the North-Eastern states). It also did
manage to provide food at lower (and more stable) prices to poor
consumers throughout the country, especially in states like Kerala
where PDS administration was better.
Universal PDS was reduced to Targeted PDS in 1997. This
meant that henceforth, only households below the official poverty
line would be ‘targeted’ by PDS. The change was brought about in
line with conditions imposed by the Structural Adjustment
Programme of the World Bank and IMF, and the reasons given
were – the state had to bear heavy subsidies, PDS was distorting
market prices and private trade, and it was incompatible with the
WTO regime. The thrust of official policy was to dismantle PDS
and rely on food grains imports, if necessary.
In March 2000, the prices of grain for above poverty line (APL)
ration card holders were increased, and the gap between prices for
below poverty line (BPL) and Above Poverty Line (APL) households
widened. 15 In many states, APL prices of grain were close to market
Of Hunger and Greed 175
that it takes ten calories of fossil fuel energy to produce one calorie
of food energy. In addition to this, an increasing proportion of world’s
food production is traded internationally, which means that the
freight (transportation) costs of food rise directly with any increase
in the price of fuel. The third significant factor behind the rise in
food prices is the irregular weather brought about by climate change.
Australia and Ukraine, major wheat exporters in the world, have
had a succession of bad harvests. Floods last year in places such as
Bangladesh and North Korea and years of low rainfall in the western
United States have also adversely affected food grain production.
Former US President George Bush has also suggested that India
and China are responsible for the present food price inflation since
“they are consuming more”. This is a ridiculous claim and only serves
to show the ignorant approach of US policymakers. However, the
growing demand for food and meat in the world (including India
and China) is likely to have contributed to the recent surge in food
prices as well.
The above factors have been listed to show that all the factors
responsible for the rise in world food prices are beyond India’s
control. All these factors are likely to worsen in the future, and
hence the rise in food prices is not a temporary or short-term
phenomenon. It is no secret that the five major-rice producing
nations of Asia (Thailand, Vietnam, Cambodia, Myanmar and Laos)
are planning to form a cartel in order to control world rice prices.33
It is thus of utmost importance that India becomes self-sufficient
in food grains production.
The need for self-sufficiency, contrary to what Prof. Amartya
Sen says, becomes even more apparent when we consider the role
of multinational agri-business corporations. Multinational
corporations dominate the global food industry today. They control
the storage, processing, distribution, trade and retail sale of large
proportions of the food consumed in the world. These agri-businesses
have had a major role to play in precipitating the present food crisis.
The speculation by these companies in the international grain
market and the hoarding of agricultural commodities has also
significantly contributed to the rise in food grains prices. Only three
companies control the world’s grain trade: Cargill, Archer Daniels
Midland and Bunge. The profits made by these three companies
(and some others) in 2007 are given in the table below. 34
182 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Notes
1. Kalpana Sharma, ‘The Sensex, Sania and Starvation’, The Hindu, 18
September 2005
2. “Wheat Imports: A Tool for Reshaping India’s Agriculture” Aspects of
India’s Economy (AIE) No. 42, RUPE.
3. Ibid.
4. Table 4 of Utsa Patnaik “Republic of Hunger” Social Scientist, Vol.
32, No. 9/10 (September-October 2004).
5. For example, if the output of a country is 100 kgs of grains in a year,
it imports 30 kgs and exports 10 kgs that year, 25 kgs get consumed
from the public stocks (of organisations like FCI) and 35 kgs are added
to the public stocks – then net availability of food in the country will
be 110 kgs [100 + (30 – 10) – (35 – 25)] that year.
Of Hunger and Greed 185
25. A possible reason why U.P. was targeted could be the absence of strong
peasant organisations in the state, unlike in Punjab and Haryana
(where the government is forced to procure from the farmers).
26. Business Standard, 17 June 2005
27. AIE No. 42 op cit
28. Bhaskar Goswami “Wheat imports: subverting procurement” 21 May
2007, www.indiatogether.org
29. Sunil “Genhu Aayat ka gorakhdhanda avam bharatiya kheti va khadya
suraksha ki vinash yojna”, Samajwadi Jan Parishad
30. “CVC squeezes government on wheat imports” The Financial Express,
30 September 2007.
31. Aseem Srivastava, “The failed harvest of food policy” Himal South
Asian, 8 June 2008
32. Ian Angus “Capitalism, agri-business and the food sovereignty
alternative”, 11 May 2008, www.globalreserch.ca
33. The Hindu, 2 May 2008
34. “Making a killing from Hunger”, www.grain.org, April 2008
35. Ibid.
36. Ibid.
Chapter IX Flaming Fields 187
Flaming Fields
Agrarian Crisis and Farmers’ Movements
against the same processes and policies which are responsible for
the agrarian crisis today. The policies of the Indian state which are
in the interests of imperialism and big capital are on the one hand,
unfavourable to the agricultural sector and on the other hand,
transfer scarce and valuable resources like land to the private
corporate sector.
In conclusion, we wish to stress the importance of collective
struggle against problems which are social and structural in nature,
like the agrarian crisis. The lack of organised opposition to state
policies is perhaps responsible for the extreme hopelessness
amongst the farmers today. Weak, scattered or disunited as they
may be, the peasant movements that exist today are the only hope
for farmers and agricultural labourers getting back their dignity
and due share in the country’s growth. All alternatives to the present
crisis in agriculture have to begin with strong movements to usher
in the same.
192 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
Appendix
Towards an Alternative
LAND REFORMS
“Land to the tiller” has been a long cherished dream of the
Indian peasantry. When this is actually realised, it is bound to
unleash the productive potential of the people. Today, the bulk of
peasantry is seeped in poverty and does not have control and (or)
ownership over land. This is largely responsible for the persisting
stagnation in the countryside. When modernisation is conceived
only in terms of technological advances, it does not address the
root cause of agrarian distress. Moreover, this modernisation is
introduced primarily in the interests of transnational corporations,
and very often works to the detriment of the farmer. Such
modernisation has certainly meant devastation for our ecology and
environment.
Thus, a key aspect for alleviating agrarian distress is
thoroughgoing land reforms and transforming the ways in which
production is organised in agriculture. Land redistribution by itself
cannot be sustainable; it must be accompanied by state support in
critical areas. Wherever fragmentation of land makes small or
marginal landholdings unviable, cooperative agriculture should be
encouraged. This also requires the advancement of human
consciousness and replacing the feudal mode of thinking with
modern and scientific ideas.
This, however, is a long drawn process. Even in the immediate
future, there are several measures that need to be taken in order
to provide support to agriculture.
SUPPORT TO AGRICULTURE
Public investment
Public investment in agriculture needs to be increased
massively. Not only should the current trend of reduction in public
investment in agriculture be reversed, but heavy investment is
required to build the rural infrastructure. Investment is required
for rural electrification, repairing the damaged soil and forestation,
leveling of soil, canal irrigation systems, water harvesting,
watershed development and rainwater management. The latter set
of measures will ensure that farmers are not only dependent on
groundwater extraction, thus conserving this important and fast
depleting natural resource. Agricultural universities set up and
funded by the state should be carrying out research in the
development of appropriate seeds and technology. Multinational
198 Harvesting Despair: Agrarian Crisis in India
seeds which are heavily dependent on water and with the opening
of agriculture to international markets. It is important that farmers
should be insured against both risks. For the former, there should
be a government sponsored insurance scheme covering all farmers
in the eventuality of crop failure in a region or district.
A system of government procurement at minimum support
prices should be in place for all regions and all crops, so that the
farmer does not have to engage in distress sale and suffer drastic
income losses in particular years. The costs of cultivation, on which
MSPs are based, should include imputed costs such as the rental
cost of owned land, and family labour. Agricultural labour should
be considered as skilled labour, and its valuation should be done
accordingly. Other anomalies in calculating the costs of cultivation
should be eliminated. The minimum support price declared by the
government, calculated as a margin over the costs of cultivation,
should act as a real floor price. For this, it is important that the
government actually undertakes procurement (through institutions
like the FCI and CCI) if market prices fall below the MSP in any
region. It is important that the government should announce MSPs
for different crops before every sowing season, so that the farmer is
able to take an informed decision about the crop he will sow in that
season.
The government must prohibit multinational corporations and
private traders from hoarding food grains and speculating in the
grain trade. Futures trading in agricultural commodities must be
banned as this increases the volatility of agricultural prices without
any benefit to the farmers.
ADDITIONAL STEPS
The Agreement on Agriculture (AoA) signed by India as part of
the WTO agreements has meant adverse consequences for the
agricultural sector with few real benefits, if any. India must
withdraw from the AoA and all other agreements which have
negative implications for our agriculture. Agricultural trade with
other countries can be carried out without entering into multilateral
agreements which are biased towards developed countries and their
farmers.
Food sovereignty for the country must be ensured. The
government must take steps to encourage the production of cereals,
pulses and edible oils and stop the diversion of agricultural land
Towards an Alternative 201
ABANDONED
Development and Displacement
Published: January 2008
Rs. 50
dgka x, os yksx
fodkl vkSj foLFkkiu
izdk'ku% flrEcj 2007
50 #-