Report | Wages, Incomes, and Wealth

Wage Stagnation in Nine Charts

Raising America's Pay

Download PDF

Our country has suffered from rising income inequality and chronically slow growth in the living standards of low- and moderate-income Americans. This disappointing living-standards growth—which was in fact caused by rising income inequality—preceded the Great Recession and continues to this day. Fortunately, income inequality and middle-class living standards are now squarely on the political agenda. But despite their increasing salience, these issues are too often discussed in abstract terms. Ignored is the easy-to-understand root of rising income inequality, slow living-standards growth, and a host of other key economic challenges: the near stagnation of hourly wage growth for the vast majority of American workers over the past generation. Countering that by generating broad-based wage growth is our core economic policy challenge.

With a group of simple charts, this paper brings the challenge we face into sharp focus, and lends clarity to the steps we must take to meet it.

It should not be surprising that trends in hourly wage growth have profound consequences for American living standards. After all, the vast majority of Americans rely on their paychecks to make ends meet. For these families, the bulk of income comes from wages and employer-provided benefits, followed by other income sources linked to jobs, such as wage-based tax credits, pensions, and social insurance. Wage-related income also accounts for the majority of total income among the bottom fifth of households.

Wage stagnation for the vast majority was not created by abstract economic trends. Rather, wages were suppressed by policy choices made on behalf of those with the most income, wealth, and power. In the past few decades, the American economy generated lots of income and wealth that would have allowed substantial living standards gains for every family. The same is true looking forward: Overall income and wealth will continue to grow. The key economic policy question is whether we will adopt policies that enable everyone to participate in a shared prosperity, or whether the growth of income and wealth will continue to accrue excessively and disproportionately to the best-off 1 percent.

The first policy choice should be to quickly restore full employment. The Federal Reserve Board can do this by not raising interest rates and slowing the recovery in the name of fighting inflationary pressures until wage growth is much, much stronger. Congress and the president can pursue the return to full employment by making public investments that can create both jobs and future productivity growth. After this, policymakers should support those labor standards that can restore some bargaining power to low- and moderate-wage workers in coming years. That means policy actions such as passing a higher minimum wage, expanding rights to overtime pay, providing paid sick leave, protecting the labor rights of undocumented workers, and restoring the right to collective bargaining. Policymakers should reject trade treaties that provide corporations greater rights and sap our manufacturing job base.

1. The cost of inequality to middle-class households

The cost of unequal growth to middle-income households

This figure shows that the stakes of rising inequality for the broad American middle class are enormous. The figure compares the income growth of the middle three-fifths of American households since 1979 to their income growth had there been no growth in inequality. In 2007, the last year before the Great Recession, the average income of the middle 60 percent of American households was $76,443. It would have been $94,310, roughly 23 percent (nearly $18,000) higher had inequality not widened (i.e., had their incomes grown at the overall average rate—an overall average buoyed by stratospheric growth at the very top). The temporary dip in top incomes during the Great Recession did little to shrink that inequality tax, which stood at 16 percent (nearly $12,000) in 2011.

Figure 1

The U.S. middle class had $17,867 less income in 2007 because of the growth of inequality since 1979: Household income of the broad middle class, actual and projected assuming no growth in inequality, 1979–2011

Actual Projected
1979/01/01 $ 61,542.17 $ 61,542.17
1980/01/01 $ 59,460.37 $ 59,579.37
1981/01/01 $ 59,210.54 $ 59,456.53
1982/01/01 $ 58,036.98 $ 59,071.83
1983/01/01 $ 57,202.97 $ 59,479.82
1984/01/01 $ 60,446.87 $ 62,779.71
1985/01/01 $ 60,428.61 $ 63,811.15
1986/01/01 $ 62,282.04 $ 68,495.45
1987/01/01 $ 61,406.97 $ 66,243.89
1988/01/01 $ 62,294.60 $ 69,102.25
1989/01/01 $ 63,153.24 $ 69,773.54
1990/01/01 $ 63,356.58 $ 69,050.00
1991/01/01 $ 62,372.76 $ 67,405.82
1992/01/01 $ 62,736.36 $ 69,303.97
1993/01/01 $ 63,537.30 $ 69,703.89
1994/01/01 $ 63,937.79 $ 70,532.26
1995/01/01 $ 65,895.09 $ 73,271.98
1996/01/01 $ 66,618.03 $ 75,655.23
1997/01/01 $ 67,717.28 $ 78,559.19
1998/01/01 $ 70,025.47 $ 82,314.50
1999/01/01 $ 71,827.31 $ 85,754.07
2000/01/01 $ 71,685.32 $ 87,083.66
2001/01/01 $ 71,738.64 $ 82,561.12
2002/01/01 $ 70,107.92 $ 79,126.24
2003/01/01 $ 70,232.82 $ 80,397.74
2004/01/01 $ 72,563.23 $ 85,031.93
2005/01/01 $ 73,700.24 $ 89,259.28
2006/01/01 $ 74,417.13 $ 91,994.00
2007/01/01 $ 76,442.90 $ 94,310.00
2008/01/01 $ 73,539.98 $ 86,971.41
2009/01/01 $ 72,708.64 $ 82,490.43
2010/01/01 $ 72,875.68 $ 84,737.13
2011/01/01 $ 72,036.33 $ 83,665.79

 

Note: Data show average income of households in the middle three-fifths.

Source: EPI analysis of Congressional Budget Office data

Reproduced from Figure I in Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge

Source: EPI analysis of data from The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2011, the Congressional Budget Office, 2014.

Reproduced from Figure I in Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge, by Josh Bivens, Elise Gould, Lawrence Mishel, and Heidi Shierholz, Economic Policy Institute, 2014.

Show table Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

2. Wage trends of the last three decades

The gap between the growth of productivity and that of a typical worker’s pay

Slow and unequal wage growth in recent decades stems from a growing wedge between overall productivity—the improvements in the amount of goods and services produced per hour worked—and the pay (wages and benefits) received by a typical worker.

The figure shows that in the three decades following World War II, hourly compensation of the vast majority of workers rose 91 percent, roughly in line with productivity growth of 97 percent. But for most of the past generation (except for a brief period in the late 1990s), pay for the vast majority lagged further and further behind overall productivity. From 1973 to 2013, hourly compensation of a typical (production/nonsupervisory) worker rose just 9 percent while productivity increased 74 percent. This breakdown of pay growth has been especially evident in the last decade, affecting both college- and non-college-educated workers as well as blue- and white-collar workers. This means that workers have been producing far more than they receive in their paychecks and benefit packages from their employers.

Figure 2

Workers produced much more, but typical workers' pay lagged far behind: Disconnect between productivity and typical worker's compensation, 1948–2013

Year Hourly compensation Productivity
1948  0.00% 0.00%
1949 6.25% 1.54%
1950 10.48% 9.33%
1951 11.76% 12.35%
1952 15.04% 15.63%
1953 20.85% 19.54%
1954 23.52% 21.56%
1955 28.74% 26.46%
1956 33.95% 26.66%
1957 37.15% 30.10%
1958 38.17% 32.79%
1959 42.55% 37.63%
1960 45.50% 40.05%
1961 48.00% 44.35%
1962 52.48% 49.79%
1963 55.03% 55.00%
1964 58.51% 59.99%
1965 62.47% 64.94%
1966 64.91% 70.00%
1967 66.90% 72.06%
1968 70.74% 77.16%
1969 74.68% 77.87%
1970 76.61% 80.38%
1971 82.03% 87.10%
1972 91.26% 92.01%
1973 91.31% 96.73%
1974 86.98% 93.62%
1975 86.86% 97.89%
1976 89.69% 103.40%
1977 93.16% 105.76%
1978 95.99% 107.76%
1979 93.39% 108.11%
1980 88.60% 106.55%
1981 87.58% 111.00%
1982 87.77% 107.87%
1983 88.34% 114.13%
1984 87.00% 119.73%
1985 86.36% 123.43%
1986 87.32% 128.00%
1987 84.64% 129.14%
1988 83.88% 131.80%
1989 83.74% 133.68%
1990 82.22% 137.01%
1991 81.91% 138.95%
1992 83.07% 147.63%
1993 83.43% 148.44%
1994 83.80% 150.82%
1995 82.69% 150.92%
1996 82.81% 157.01%
1997 84.82% 160.63%
1998 89.16% 165.86%
1999 91.96% 172.76%
2000 93.03% 179.18%
2001 95.70% 183.50%
2002 99.61% 191.43%
2003 101.80% 200.93%
2004 101.11% 209.10%
2005 100.21% 214.53%
2006 100.31% 216.46%
2007 101.83% 218.75%
2008 101.95% 219.36%
2009 109.88% 225.95%
2010 111.85% 235.39%
2011 109.27% 236.71%
2012 107.53% 240.85%
2013 108.86% 243.13%

Note: Data are for compensation (wages and benefits) of production/nonsupervisory workers in the private sector and net productivity of the total economy. "Net productivity" is the growth of output of goods and services less depreciation per hour worked.

Source: EPI analysis of Bureau of Labor Statistics and Bureau of Economic Analysis data

Updated from Figure A in Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge

Source: EPI analysis of unpublished Total Economy Productivity data from Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Labor Productivity and Costs program, wage data from the BLS Current Employment Statistics, BLS Employment Cost Trends, BLS Consumer Price Index, and Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Product Accounts

Updated from Figure A in Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge, by Josh Bivens, Elise Gould, Lawrence Mishel, and Heidi Shierholz, Economic Policy Institute, 2014.

Show table Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Wage growth of the top 1%

The ability of those at the very top to claim an ever-larger share of overall wages is evident in this figure. Two things stand out. First is the extraordinarily rapid growth of annual wages for the top 1 percent compared with everybody else: Top 1 percent wages grew 138 percent, while wages of the bottom 90 percent grew just 15 percent. If the wages of the bottom 90 percent had grown at the average pace over this period—meaning that wages grew equally across-the-board—then the bottom 90 percent’s wages would have grown by 32 percent, more than double the actual growth.

Figure 3

When it comes to the pace of annual pay increases, the top 1% wage grew 138% since 1979, while wages for the bottom 90% grew 15%: Cumulative change in real annual wages, by wage group, 1979–2013

Top 1% Bottom 90%
1979 0.0% 0.0%
1980 3.4% -2.2%
1981 3.1% -2.6%
1982 9.5% -3.9%
1983 13.6% -3.7%
1984 20.7% -1.8%
1985 23.0% -1.0%
1986 32.6% 1.1%
1987 53.5% 2.1%
1988 68.7% 2.2%
1989 63.3% 1.8%
1990 64.8% 1.1%
1991 53.6% 0.0%
1992 74.3% 1.5%
1993 67.9% 0.9%
1994 63.4% 2.0%
1995 70.2% 2.8%
1996 79.0% 4.1%
1997 100.6% 7.0%
1998 113.1% 11.0%
1999 129.7% 13.2%
2000 144.8% 15.3%
2001 130.4% 15.7%
2002 109.3% 15.6%
2003 113.9% 15.7%
2004 127.2% 15.6%
2005 135.4% 15.0%
2006 143.4% 15.7%
2007 156.2% 16.7%
2008 137.5% 16.0%
2009 116.2% 16.0%
2010 130.9% 15.2%
2011 134.1% 14.6%
2012 148.4% 14.7%
2013 137.7% 15.2%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Source: EPI analysis of data from Kopczuk, Saez, and Song (2010) and Social Security Administration wage statistics

Reproduced from Figure F in Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge

Source: EPI analysis of data from “Earnings Inequality and Mobility in the United States: Evidence from Social Security Data Since 1937,” by Wojciech Kopczuk, Emmanuel Saez, and Jae Song, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 2010; updated through 2013 with data from the Social Security Administration Wage Statistics database.

Reproduced from Figure F in Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge, by Josh Bivens, Elise Gould, Lawrence Mishel, and Heidi Shierholz, Economic Policy Institute, 2014.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Stagnant wages for middle-wage workers, declining wages for low-wage workers

Over the entire 34-year period between 1979 and 2013, the hourly wages of middle-wage workers (median-wage workers who earned more than half the workforce but less than the other half) were stagnant, rising just 6 percent—less than 0.2 percent per year. This wage growth, in fact, occurred only because wages grew in the late 1990s when labor markets got tight enough—unemployment, for instance, fell to 4 percent in 1999 and 2000—to finally deliver across-the-board hourly wage growth. The wages of middle-wage workers were totally flat or in decline over the 1980s, 1990s and 2000s, except for the late 1990s. The wages of low-wage workers fared even worse, falling 5 percent from 1979 to 2013. In contrast, the hourly wages of high-wage workers rose 41 percent.

Figure 4

Middle-class wages are stagnant—Middle-wage workers' hourly wage is up 6% since 1979, low-wage workers' wages are down 5%, while those with very high wages saw a 41% increase: Cumulative change in real hourly wages of all workers, by wage percentile,* 1979–2013

YEAR Very high wage Middle wage Low wage
1979/01/01 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%
1980/01/01 -1.90% -1.00% -5.50%
1981/01/01 -1.70% -3.60% -4.00%
1982/01/01 0.20% -2.20% -7.70%
1983/01/01 3.40% -2.70% -10.50%
1984/01/01 4.20% -2.20% -12.70%
1985/01/01 6.00% -1.30% -14.10%
1986/01/01 7.60% 0.50% -14.30%
1987/01/01 7.40% 0.60% -14.50%
1988/01/01 10.10% 0.00% -14.50%
1989/01/01 7.50% -0.60% -14.60%
1990/01/01 9.60% -0.60% -13.10%
1991/01/01 10.30% 0.00% -11.50%
1992/01/01 8.50% 0.80% -11.70%
1993/01/01 7.60% 0.10% -12.00%
1994/01/01 13.10% -1.60% -12.90%
1995/01/01 13.20% -2.40% -13.10%
1996/01/01 13.80% -2.80% -13.50%
1997/01/01 15.20% -0.50% -10.60%
1998/01/01 18.00% 2.30% -5.70%
1999/01/01 21.50% 5.40% -4.30%
2000/01/01 25.20% 5.10% -3.40%
2001/01/01 27.70% 7.40% -0.40%
2002/01/01 32.00% 8.30% 0.70%
2003/01/01 30.30% 9.60% 0.30%
2004/01/01 31.60% 9.60% -1.10%
2005/01/01 32.50% 8.30% -2.80%
2006/01/01 33.20% 8.70% -2.20%
2007/01/01 36.10% 7.80% -1.00%
2008/01/01 37.60% 8.30% -1.90%
2009/01/01 39.00% 10.10% -1.10%
2010/01/01 38.70% 8.60% -1.90%
2011/01/01 37.10% 5.70% -4.30%
2012/01/01 39.00% 5.00% -5.90%
2013/01/01 40.60% 6.10% -5.30%

 

ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

* Low wage is 10th percentile, middle wage is 50th percentile, very high wage is 95th percentile.

Source: EPI analysis of Current Population Survey Outgoing Rotation Group microdata

Reproduced from Figure F in Why America’s Workers Need Faster Wage Growth—And What We Can Do About It

Source: EPI analysis of Current Population Survey Outgoing Rotation Group microdata from the CPS survey con­ducted by the Bureau of the Census for the Bureau of Labor Statistics [machine-readable microdata file]. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Census Bureau.

Reproduced from Figure F in Why America’s Workers Need Faster Wage Growth—And What We Can Do About It, by Elise Gould, Economic Policy Institute, 2014

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

The wage and benefit plight of recent college graduates

The widespread problem of stagnant hourly wages is not a problem of insufficiently skilled or educated workers. As this figure shows, a four-year college degree has been no guarantee of decent wage growth. In 2013, inflation-adjusted hourly wages of young college graduates were lower than they were in the late 1990s, a trend that held for both young male and female college graduates. Thus, wage stagnation and erosion afflict even the one-third of workers who have earned a four-year college degree.

Figure 5

Wages of young college grads have been falling since 2000: Real average hourly wages of young college graduates, 1989–2014

 Year All Men Women
1989 $16.59 $17.24 $16.12
1990 $17.10 $18.12 $16.37
1991 $16.39 $17.34 $15.67
1992 $15.82 $16.39 $15.39
1993 $15.89 $16.63 $15.34
1994 $15.88 $16.95 $15.08
1995 $15.45 $16.21 $14.91
1996 $15.59 $15.94 $15.34
1997 $16.19 $17.32 $15.36
1998 $17.96 $20.12 $16.34
1999 $18.07 $18.82 $17.58
2000 $18.41 $19.24 $17.82
2001 $18.55 $20.00 $17.51
2002 $18.33 $19.78 $17.36
2003 $17.68 $18.42 $17.13
2004 $17.97 $18.79 $17.38
2005 $17.67 $19.13 $16.66
2006 $17.85 $18.80 $17.20
2007 $18.24 $19.95 $17.00
2008 $17.87 $18.55 $17.39
2009 $18.33 $20.48 $16.85
2010 $17.29 $18.87 $16.21
2011 $17.41 $18.96 $16.30
2012 $16.85 $18.07 $15.87
2013 $17.04 $18.92 $15.54
2013-04-01 $16.99 $19.15 $15.29
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Data are for college graduates age 21–24 who do not have an advanced degree and are not enrolled in further schooling. Data for 2014 represent 12-month average from April 2013–March 2014. Shaded areas denote recessions.

Source: EPI analysis of Current Population Survey Outgoing Rotation Group microdata

Adapted from Figure N in The Class of 2014The Weak Economy Is Idling Too Many Young Graduates

Source: EPI analysis of Current Population Survey Outgoing Rotation Group microdata from the CPS survey con­ducted by the Bureau of the Census for the Bureau of Labor Statistics [machine-readable microdata file]. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Census Bureau.

 

Adapted from Figure N in The Class of 2014 The Weak Economy Is Idling Too Many Young Graduates by Heidi Shierholz, Alyssa Davis, and Will Kimball, Economic Policy Institute, 2014

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Recent college graduates have been less and less able to find jobs that provide health insurance. The share of young college graduates who have employer-sponsored health insurance coverage fell from 61 percent in 1989 to 31 percent by 2012. Most of this health-benefit erosion occurred since 2000, when just over half (53 percent) of recent college graduates had employer-provided health insurance. For high-school graduates, the decline was even steeper, from 24 percent in 1989 to just 7 percent in 2012.

Figure 6

Employers are cutting health care for young workers, both college and high school graduates: Share of employed recent high school and college graduates with health insurance provided by their own employer, 1989–2012

High school graduates College graduates
1989/01/01 23.5% 60.7%
1990/01/01 21.9% 53.8%
1991/01/01 18.7% 56.2%
1992/01/01 14.3% 46.8%
1993/01/01 14.7% 48.4%
1994/01/01 17.1% 49.8%
1995/01/01 17.4% 51.5%
1996/01/01 15.0% 51.1%
1997/01/01 16.8% 48.0%
1998/01/01 16.6% 49.4%
1999/01/01 18.0% 49.4%
2000/01/01 20.1% 53.1%
2001/01/01 18.5% 49.2%
2002/01/01 14.8% 46.6%
2003/01/01 13.4% 41.0%
2004/01/01 12.3% 47.4%
2005/01/01 11.8% 44.8%
2006/01/01 13.2% 52.4%
2007/01/01 12.4% 51.4%
2008/01/01 9.8% 46.3%
2009/01/01 8.6% 40.5%
2010/01/01 5.3% 36.2%
2011/01/01 7.1% 31.1%
2012/01/01 6.6% 30.9%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Coverage is defined as being included in an employer-provided plan where the employer paid for at least some of the coverage. Data are for college graduates age 21–24 who do not have an advanced degree and are not enrolled in further schooling, and high school graduates age 17–20 who are not enrolled in further schooling. Shaded areas denote recessions.

Source: EPI analysis of Current Population Annual Social and Economic Supplement microdata

Reproduced from Figure O in The Class of 2014: The Weak Economy Is Idling Too Many Young Graduates

Source: EPI analysis of Current Population Survey Annual Social and Economic Supplement (CPS ASEC) microdata, Survey conducted by the Bureau of the Census for the Bureau of Labor Statistics [machine-readable microdata file]. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Census Bureau.

Reproduced from Figure O in The Class of 2014: The Weak Economy Is Idling Too Many Young Graduates by Heidi Shierholz, Alyssa Davis, and Will Kimball, Economic Policy Institute, 2014

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

3. Factors driving wage stagnation and inequality

CEO pay grabs a larger share of wages

In a nation of increasing inequality, the most extreme wage disparities are between the heads of large American corporations and typical workers. This figure tracks the ratio of pay of CEOs at the 350 largest public U.S. firms to the pay of typical workers in those firms’ industries. In 1965, these CEOs made 20 times what typical workers made. As of 2013, they make just under 300 times typical workers’ pay. This higher pay for CEOs does not reflect any increased contribution to corporate output: Other data show that CEO pay grew three times faster than the pay of the top 0.1 percent of wage earners and twice as fast as corporate profits. Moreover, the rising pay of executives was the largest factor in the doubling of the top 0.1 percent and top 1.0 percent share of overall household income growth. CEO pay gains help explain the growing divergence between pay and productivity.

Figure 7

CEOs now make 296 times what a typical worker earns : CEO-to-worker compensation ratio, 1965–2013

Year Interpolated values
1965/01/01 20.0
1966/01/01 20.0
1967/01/01 20.0
1968/01/01 23.7
1969/01/01 23.7
1970/01/01 23.7
1971/01/01 23.7
1972/01/01 23.7
1973/01/01 22.3
1974/01/01 22.3
1975/01/01 22.3
1976/01/01 22.4
1977/01/01 22.4
1978/01/01 29.9
1979/01/01 29.9
1980/01/01 29.9
1981/01/01 29.9
1982/01/01 29.9
1983/01/01 29.9
1984/01/01 29.9
1985/01/01 29.9
1986/01/01 29.9
1987/01/01 29.9
1988/01/01 29.9
1989/01/01 58.7
1990/01/01 58.8
1991/01/01 58.8
1992/01/01 104.4
1993/01/01 111.8
1994/01/01 87.3
1995/01/01 122.6
1996/01/01 153.8
1997/01/01 233.0
1998/01/01 321.8
1999/01/01 286.7
2000/01/01 383.4
2001/01/01 214.2
2002/01/01 188.5 
2003/01/01 227.5
2004/01/01 256.6
2005/01/01 308.0
2006/01/01 341.4
2007/01/01 351.3
2008/01/01 234.3
2009/01/01 193.2
2010/01/01 227.9
2011/01/01 231.8
2012/01/01 278.2
2013/01/01 295.9
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: CEO annual compensation is computed using the "options realized" compensation series for CEOs at the top 350 U.S. firms ranked by sales. Typical worker compensation is average compensation of production/nonsupervisory workers in the key industries of the firms included in the sample.

Note: CEO annual compensation is computed using the "options realized" compensation series for CEOs at the top 350 U.S. firms ranked by sales. Typical worker compensation is average compensation of production/nonsupervisory workers in the key industries of the firms included in the sample.

The options-realized compensation series includes salary, bonus, restricted stock grants, options exercised, and long-term incentive payouts. Facebook's CEO is excluded from the samples in 2012 and 2013 (the only years for which the firm has been public) because his compensation is such an outlier (compensation of $2.3 billion in 2012 and $3.3 billion in 2013) that including it would have dramatically altered the results.

Source: EPI analysis of data from Compustat's ExecuComp database, Bureau of Labor Statistics Current Employment Statistics, and Bureau of Economic Analysis NIPA tables

Reproduced from Figure C in CEO Pay Continues to Rise as Typical Workers Are Paid Less

Source: EPI analysis of data from Compustat's ExecuComp database; Bureau of Labor Statistics Current Employment Statistics, Employment, Hours and Earnings-National database; and Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Product Accounts tables 6.2C, 6.2D, 6.3C, and 6.3D

Reproduced from Figure C in CEO Pay Continues to Rise as Typical Workers Are Paid Less, by Lawrence Mishel and Alyssa Davis, Economic Policy Institute, 2014.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Policy choices regarding the minimum wage fuel wage inequality

While pay at the top of the labor market has outpaced nearly every labor market indicator for decades, pay at the bottom—the federal minimum wage—has severely lagged. This figure shows the decline in the real (inflation-adjusted) value of the minimum wage since its high in 1968 as well as what the federal minimum wage would be today if it had kept pace with the growth of real hourly wages of production and nonsupervisory workers (who make up 80 percent of the workforce) or economy-wide productivity. Had the federal minimum wage kept pace with productivity it would be over $18 today. Though not shown in the figure, the federal minimum wage did keep pace with productivity in the 30 years before 1968.

The minimum wage essentially establishes the wage levels of the bottom fifth of wage earners. These low-wage workers are far more educated and are older than low-wage workers in 1968. Yet, despite being more skilled and productive, the wages they earn are lower than wages earned in 1968. The failure to raise the minimum wage had especially adverse effects on women and minority workers.

Figure 8

The minimum wage would be over $18 had it risen along with productivity: Real value of the federal minimum wage compared with its value had it grown at the rate of productivity and average hourly wages, 1968–2014

Year Real minimum wage Real hourly wage Productivity 
1968  $                    9.58  $                       9.58  $                     9.58
1969  $                    9.17  $                       9.78  $                     9.62
1970  $                    8.75  $                       9.85  $                     9.76
1971  $                    8.38  $                     10.07  $                  10.12
1972  $                    8.14  $                     10.51  $                  10.39
1973  $                    7.65  $                     10.49  $                  10.64
1974  $                    8.70  $                     10.21  $                  10.47
1975  $                    8.44  $                     10.07  $                  10.70
1976  $                    8.74  $                     10.19  $                  11.00
1977  $                    8.22  $                     10.30  $                  11.13
1978  $                    8.86  $                     10.42  $                  11.24
1979  $                    8.85  $                     10.25  $                  11.26
1980  $                    8.52  $                       9.97  $                  11.17
1981  $                    8.40  $                       9.89  $                  11.41
1982  $                    7.93  $                       9.86  $                  11.24
1983  $                    7.60  $                       9.86  $                  11.58
1984  $                    7.30  $                       9.80  $                  11.88
1985  $                    7.06  $                       9.76  $                  12.08
1986  $                    6.93  $                       9.79  $                  12.33
1987  $                    6.71  $                       9.70  $                  12.39
1988  $                    6.47  $                       9.66  $                  12.54
1989  $                    6.20  $                       9.61  $                  12.64
1990  $                    6.70  $                       9.53  $                  12.82
1991  $                    7.24  $                       9.48  $                  12.92
1992  $                    7.06  $                       9.47  $                  13.39
1993  $                    6.89  $                       9.49  $                  13.43
1994  $                    6.74  $                       9.53  $                  13.56
1995  $                    6.58  $                       9.56  $                  13.57
1996  $                    7.17  $                       9.63  $                  13.90
1997  $                    7.61  $                       9.79  $                  14.09
1998  $                    7.50  $                     10.04  $                  14.37
1999  $                    7.35  $                     10.20  $                  14.72
2000  $                    7.11  $                     10.26  $                  15.07
2001  $                    6.92  $                     10.35  $                  15.30
2002  $                    6.81  $                     10.48  $                  15.73
2003  $                    6.66   $                     10.53   $                  16.24 
2004  $                    6.48  $                     10.46  $                  16.68
2005  $                    6.27  $                     10.40  $                  16.97
2006  $                    6.07  $                     10.47  $                  17.07
2007  $                    6.71  $                     10.58  $                  17.19
2008  $                    7.23  $                     10.57  $                  17.22
2009  $                    8.04  $                     10.93  $                  17.58
2010  $                    7.91  $                     11.01  $                  18.09
2011  $                    7.66  $                     10.89  $                  18.12
2012  $                    7.51  $                     10.83  $                  18.26
2013  $                    7.40  $                     10.89  $                  18.43
2014  $                    7.25   $                     10.89   $                  18.42 
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Real average hourly wages are of production/nonsupervisory workers in the private sector, and productivity is net productivity of the total economy.

Note: Real average hourly wages are of production/nonsupervisory workers  in the private sector, and productivity is net productivity of the total economy. 2014 values reflect average of the first half of 2014.

Source: EPI analysis of data from the U.S. Department of Labor's Bureau of Labor Statistics and Labor Wage and Hour Division

Source: Productivity data are unpublished data from the BLS Labor Productivity and Costs program's Major Sector Productivity and Costs and Industry Productivity and Costs databases; wage data come from the BLS Current Employment Statistics program's Employment, Hours and Earnings—National database; Current Population Survey Outgoing Rotation Group microdata from the CPS survey con­ducted by the Bureau of the Census for the Bureau of Labor Statistics;  and U.S. Department of Labor Wage and Hour Division's online chart, “History of Federal Minimum Wage Rates Under the Fair Labor Standards Act, 1938-2009.

Adapted from Raising the Federal Minimum Wage to $10.10 Would Save Safety Net Programs Billions and Help Ensure Businesses Are Doing Their Fair Share, by David Cooper, Economic Policy Institute, 2014.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

The erosion of collective bargaining hurts all workers

One of the main causes of stagnant wages and rising wage inequality is the decline of collective bargaining which has lowered the wages of both union and nonunion workers. The figure shows that the drop in the share of workers under collective bargaining contracts is the mirror image of the rise of incomes of the top 10 percent. This occurs because collective bargaining not only raises wages for organized workers but also leads other employers to raise the wages and benefits of nonunion workers to come closer to union wage standards. This phenomenon occurs when collective bargaining achieves even modest penetration. The erosion of collective bargaining can explain from one-fourth to one-third of the growth of wage inequality between 1973 and 2007 and had a greater impact on men than women. This erosion of collective bargaining occurred despite large numbers of workers indicating they would prefer collective bargaining if they had a choice. But the political power of those with the most income, wealth, and power prevented the adoption of laws to modernize our labor–management system and enable workers to pursue collective bargaining.

Figure 9

Decline in union membership mirrors income gains of top 10%: Union membership and share of income going to the top 10%, 1917–2012

Year Union membership Share of income going to the top 10 percent
1917 11.0% 40.3%
1918 12.1% 39.9%
1919 14.3% 39.5%
1920 17.5% 38.1%
1921 17.6% 42.9%
1922 14.0% 43.0%
1923 11.7% 40.6%
1924 11.3% 43.3%
1925 11.0% 44.2%
1926 10.7% 44.1%
1927 10.6% 44.7%
1928 10.4% 46.1%
1929 10.1% 43.8%
1930 10.7% 43.1%
1931 11.2% 44.4%
1932 11.3% 46.3%
1933 9.5% 45.0%
1934 9.8% 45.2%
1935 10.8% 43.4%
1936 11.1% 44.8%
1937 18.6% 43.4%
1938 23.9% 43.0%
1939 24.8% 44.6%
1940 23.5% 44.4%
1941 25.4% 41.0%
1942 24.2% 35.5%
1943 30.1% 32.7%
1944 32.5% 31.6%
1945 33.4% 32.6%
1946 31.9% 34.6%
1947 31.1% 33.0%
1948 30.5% 33.7%
1949 29.6% 33.8%
1950 30.0% 33.9%
1951 32.4% 32.8%
1952 31.5% 32.1%
1953 33.2% 31.4%
1954 32.7% 32.1%
1955 32.9% 31.8%
1956 33.2% 31.8%
1957 32.0% 31.7%
1958 31.1% 32.1%
1959 31.6% 32.0%
1960 30.7% 31.7%
1961 28.7% 31.9%
1962 29.1% 32.0%
1963 28.5% 32.0%
1964 28.5% 31.6%
1965 28.6% 31.5%
1966 28.7% 32.0%
1967 28.6% 32.1%
1968 28.7% 32.0%
1969 28.3% 31.8%
1970 27.9% 31.5%
1971 27.4% 31.8%
1972 27.5% 31.6%
1973 27.1% 31.9%
1974 26.5% 32.4%
1975 25.7% 32.6%
1976 25.7% 32.4%
1977 25.2% 32.4%
1978 24.7% 32.4%
1979 25.4% 32.4%
1980 23.6% 32.9%
1981 22.3% 32.7%
1982 21.6% 33.2%
1983 21.4% 33.7%
1984 20.5% 34.0%
1985 19.0% 34.3%
1986 18.5% 34.6%
1987 17.9% 36.5%
1988 17.6% 38.6%
1989 17.2% 38.5%
1990 16.7% 38.8%
1991 16.2% 38.4%
1992 16.2% 39.8%
1993 16.2% 39.5%
1994 16.1% 39.6%
1995 15.3% 40.5%
1996 14.9% 41.2%
1997 14.7% 41.7%
1998 14.2% 42.1%
1999 14.2% 42.7%
2000 13.6% 43.1%
2001 13.7% 42.2%
2002 13.5% 42.4%
2003 13.0% 42.8%
2004 12.6% 43.6%
2005 12.5% 44.9%
2006 12.0% 45.5%
2007 12.1% 45.7%
2008 12.5% 46.0%
2009 12.4% 45.5%
2010 11.9% 46.4%
2011 11.8% 46.6%
2012 11.3% 48.2%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Source: Data on union density follow the composite series found in Historical Statistics of the United States, updated to 2012 from unionstats.com. Income inequality (share of income to top 10%) from Piketty and Saez, “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913-1998," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 2003, 1–39. Updated and downloadable data, for this series and other countries, are available at The World's Top Income Database. Updated September 2013.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Other factors behind stagnating American wages

This paper provides a brief overview of some of the causes of wage stagnation and inequality. Sources in the references section provide a more complete analysis. Excessive unemployment, not only during and after the Great Recession but over most years since 1979, has suppressed wage growth, adversely affecting low-wage workers more than middle-wage workers but having little impact on high-wage workers. Global integration with low-wage countries, accelerated by particular trade policies (e.g., admission of China to the World Trade Organization in the late 1990s) has adversely affected wages of non–college educated workers. The erosion of labor standards (beyond the decline in the real value of the minimum wage) and weak enforcement have also put downward pressure on wages. Extensive wage theft, worker misclassification, weakened prevailing wage laws and overtime protections, and the failure to modernize our labor standards to provide sick leave, family leave, or minimum vacation schedules all hurt wage growth. The increased presence of undocumented workers who are vulnerable to employer exploitation also undercuts not only the wages of these workers but also those in similar fields.

— The authors thank EPI research assistants Tanyell Cooke, Alyssa Davis, and Will Kimball for their valuable assistance in preparing the charts in this report.

About the authors

Lawrence Mishel, a nationally recognized economist, has been president of the Economic Policy Institute since 2002. Prior to that he was EPI’s first research director (starting in 1987) and later became vice president. He is the coauthor of all 12 editions of The State of Working America. He holds a Ph.D. in economics from the University of Wisconsin at Madison, and his articles have appeared in a variety of academic and non-academic journals. His areas of research are labor economics, wage and income distribution, industrial relations, productivity growth, and the economics of education.

Elise Gould joined EPI as an economist in 2003 and is the institute’s director of health policy research. Her research areas include employer-sponsored health insurance, inequality and health, poverty, economic mobility, and the employer tax exclusion. She is a coauthor of The State of Working America, 12th Edition. In the past, she has authored a chapter on health in The State of Working America 2008/09; coauthored a book on health insurance coverage in retirement; published in venues such as The Chronicle of Higher EducationChallenge Magazine, and Tax Notes; and written for academic journals including Health EconomicsHealth Affairs, Journal of Aging and Social Policy, Risk Management & Insurance Review, Environmental Health Perspectives, and International Journal of Health Services. She holds a master’s in public affairs from the University of Texas at Austin and a Ph.D. in economics from the University of Wisconsin at Madison.

Josh Bivens joined the Economic Policy Institute in 2002 and is currently the director of research and policy. His primary areas of research include mac­roeconomics, social insurance, and globalization. He has authored or coauthored three books (including The State of Working America, 12th Edition) while working at EPI, edited another, and has written numerous research papers, including for academic journals. He appears often in media outlets to offer eco­nomic commentary and has testified several times before the U.S. Congress. He earned his Ph.D. from The New School for Social Research.

References

CEO Pay Continues to Rise as Typical Workers Are Paid Less, by Lawrence Mishel and Alyssa Davis, Economic Policy Institute, 2014

How Unions Help All Workers, by Lawrence Mishel and Matthew Walters, Economic Policy Institute, 2003

Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge, by Josh Bivens, Elise Gould, Lawrence Mishel, and Heidi Shierholz, Economic Policy Institute, 2014

Raising the Federal Minimum Wage to $10.10 Would Save Safety Net Programs Billions and Help Ensure Businesses Are Doing Their Fair Share, by David Cooper, Economic Policy Institute, 2014

The Class of 2014: The Weak Economy Is Idling Too Many Young Graduates, by Heidi Shierholz, Alyssa Davis, and Will Kimball, Economic Policy Institute, 2014

The State of Working America, 12th Edition, by Lawrence Mishel, Josh Bivens, Elise Gould, and Heidi Shierholz, Economic Policy Institute and Cornell University Press, 2012; updated online at www.stateofworkingamerica.org/

Unions, Inequality, and Faltering Middle-class Wages, by Lawrence Mishel, Economic Policy Institute, 2012

Wage Inequality: A Story of Policy Choices,” by Heidi Shierholz, Lawrence Mishel, and John Schmitt, New Labor Forum, August 4, 2014

Why America’s Workers Need Faster Wage Growth—And What We Can Do About It, by Elise Gould, Economic Policy Institute, 2014